• Macroeconomics

Zimbabwe: A Case Study of Hyperinflation

zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

  • Distribute all flashcards reviewing into small sessions
  • Get inspired with a daily photo
  • Import sets from Anki, Quizlet, etc
  • Add Active Recall to your learning and get higher grades!

Related documents

View the presentation - Winning Women Worldwide

Add this document to collection(s)

You can add this document to your study collection(s)

Add this document to saved

You can add this document to your saved list

Suggest us how to improve StudyLib

(For complaints, use another form )

Input it if you want to receive answer

Union | Digital Works

Home > Student Work > Honors Theses > 1175

Honors Theses

Hyperinflation in zimbabwe : case study and analysis of money velocity.

Kenrick L. Liu , Union College - Schenectady, NY Follow

Date of Award

Document type.

Union College Only

Degree Name

Bachelor of Arts

First Advisor

Bradley Lewis

inflation, money, velocity, data, clear

Hyperinflation, defined as inflation of over 50 percent month-over-month, in Zimbabwe began in March 2007. However, the economy has been plagued with annual inflation of over 20 percent since the early 1990s. Once regarded as the bread basket of Africa, Zimbabwe’s political mismanagement has destroyed its own economic wellbeing. Were the government and central bank so ignorant as to lead the economy down this path? This study examines the political issues surrounding monetary mismanagement and the clear disregard for monetary theory. In addition, Irving Fisher’s Equation of Exchange is used to examine Zimbabwean money supply velocity for a period of almost 30 years. I examine velocity before and during the dramatic rise in inflation. In order to investigate this variable, I used data from the World Development Indicators Database to compile nominal GDP and money supply (M2) figures. While this data are available from 1980 to 2007, accurate measurement of any economic data was compromised in the late 2000s because of hyperinflation. Factors such as a shortage of food and cash combined with rapid increases in prices do not provide a clear theoretical direction for money velocity. Results show a dramatic fall in money velocity beginning in 2000 due to consumers refusing to do transactions in the local currency. The level of inflation as well as the lack of confidence in the government caused people to use the South African rand and U.S. dollar instead.

Recommended Citation

Liu, Kenrick L., "Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe : case study and analysis of money velocity" (2010). Honors Theses . 1175. https://digitalworks.union.edu/theses/1175

Since June 22, 2018

Advanced Search

  • Notify me via email or RSS
  • Collections
  • Disciplines

Author Corner

  • Liberal Arts Research Commons
  • Schaffer Library

Home | About | FAQ | My Account | Accessibility Statement

Privacy Copyright

The Effects of Inflation on Preparation of Financial Statements of the Retail Sector in Zimbabwe: A Case Study of OK Zimbabwe Limited (2018–2019)

62 Pages Posted: 3 Sep 2020

Anthony Tapiwa Mazikana

University of Zimbabwe

Date Written: July 25, 2020

The effects of inflation on preparation of financial statements of the retail sector in Zimbabwe over recent decades. Inflation is broadly defined by many scholars as a general increase in prices and fall in the purchasing value of money. Although a considerable inflation knowledge base exists in Zimbabwean SMEs, there have been no comprehensive studies on inflation in retail organizations which has been conducted. This study sought to determine what an inflationary economy is, identify the causes and types of inflation, determine the degree of impact to the preparation of financial statement in an inflationary economy, ascertain any operational benefits the retail sector likely to accrue by operating in an inflationary environment and recommend possible strategies to enhance proper preparation of financial statements. The literature on inflation showed that the following areas have not been explored: the meaning attached to an inflationary economy is by OK Zimbabwe is currently unknown, the impact of inflation to the preparation of financial statement in an inflationary economy, Zimbabwe is currently unknown, and operational benefits the retail sector likely to accrue by operating in an inflationary environment are currently unknown. Data for this study was collected through 234 questionnaires and six semi-structured and open-ended interviews with owner-managers of OK Zimbabwe. The systematic random sampling method was used to select respondents for quantitative research while the purposive method was used to select respondents for qualitative research. The SPSS version 20.0 was adopted to analyze quantitative data while the reduction method was adopted for qualitative data. Findings reveal that there is no standard meaning for inflationary economy is in Zimbabwe. OK Zimbabwe considers inflation as something which has an impact to the preparation of financial statement in an inflationary economy.

Keywords: inflation, inflationary economy, financial statements

Suggested Citation: Suggested Citation

Anthony Tapiwa Mazikana (Contact Author)

University of zimbabwe ( email ).

c/o Hall Farm, Wenhaston Suffolk Ip19 9HE, Mashonaland Zimbabwe

Do you have a job opening that you would like to promote on SSRN?

Paper statistics, related ejournals, econometrics: econometric & statistical methods - special topics ejournal.

Subscribe to this fee journal for more curated articles on this topic

Macroeconomics: Prices, Business Fluctuations, & Cycles eJournal

Econometrics: data collection & data estimation methodology ejournal, development economics: macroeconomic issues in developing economies ejournal, emerging markets economics: firm behavior & microeconomic issues ejournal, emerging markets: theory & practice ejournal.

Logo

  • Previous Article
  • Next Article

This paper examines the challenges and policy options after hyperinflation in Zimbabwe. The paper reviews the pros and cons of alternative monetary regimes for Zimbabwe to succeed the current multicurrency system, which the authorities consider a temporary arrangement. The analysis suggests that some form of official dollarization has significant advantages. The paper also assesses competitiveness and external sustainability in debt-distressed Zimbabwe. It also makes a case for creating fiscal space for growth and development in post-hyperinflation Zimbabwe.

  • Chapter 1. Introduction

Following a decade of economic decline and hyperinflation during 2007—08, Zimbabwe’s economy has started to grow. The nascent economic recovery has been supported by a significant improvement in economic policies, but important policy challenges and significant vulnerabilities remain to be addressed. A collection of three papers presents current pressing economic issues and possible options for their resolution.

Chapter 2 reviews the pros and cons of alternative monetary regimes for Zimbabwe to succeed the current multi-currency system, which the authorities consider a temporary arrangement. The analysis suggests that some form of official dollarization has significant advantages. Arrangements with the Zimbabwe dollar as sole legal tender could be unstable in the absence of a sufficiently long track record of sound policies.

Chapter 3 assesses competitiveness and external sustainability in debt-distressed Zimbabwe. Although the country may be rich in mineral resources, significant problems with the business climate make it difficult to accelerate their extraction. Staff estimates indicate that the net present value of both net mining export receipts and resource-related budget revenues are not sufficient to resolve external payments arrears. Thus, bringing resource revenue forward (e.g., by mortgaging the future resource cash flow) would not by itself eliminate debt overhang.

Chapter 4 makes a case for creating fiscal space for growth and development in post-hyperinflation Zimbabwe. The analysis indicates that a combination of revenue-enhancing measures and wage restraint could generate fiscal space of about 5 percent of GDP, which would help improve delivery of public service and rehabilitate infrastructure.

Chapter 2. Choosing a Monetary Regime 1

In late 2008, hyperinflation led to abandonment of the Zimbabwe dollar in transactions and de facto widespread dollarization . The official recognition of the demise of the Zimbabwe dollar took place in February 2009, when authorities established a multicurrency system. Under this system, transactions in hard foreign currencies are authorized, payments of taxes are mandatory in foreign exchange, and the exchange system largely is liberalized. 2 Since the abolition of all surrender requirements on foreign exchange proceeds on March 19, 2009, there has not been a functioning foreign exchange market for Zimbabwe dollars. Bank accounts denominated in Zimbabwe dollars (equivalent to about US$6 million at the exchange rate of Z$35 quadrillion per US$1) are dormant. Use of the Zimbabwe dollar as domestic currency has been discontinued until 2012.

While five foreign currencies have been granted official status, the U.S. dollar has become the principal currency. 3 Budget revenue estimates and the budget expenditure allocations for 2009 were denominated in U.S. dollars, and the subsequent budget for 2010 was also denominated in U.S. dollars. For noncash transactions, the market is exhibiting a strong preference for the U.S. dollar: banks estimate that some four-fifths of all transactions are taking place in U.S. dollars, including most wage payments. Furthermore, stock exchange trading takes place in U.S. dollars, the payments systems operate in U.S. dollars, and the banking system and the Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe (RBZ) maintain accounting in U.S. dollars. In cash transactions, the U.S. dollar is the currency of choice, but the rand is prevalent in the South of the country, and it also circulates in the rest of the country, in particular coins. Wider circulation of the rand is prevented by South Africa’s capital account controls ( Appendix II—2 , Box II—2.1 ). Currencies other than the U.S. dollar and the rand have limited circulation in Zimbabwe.

The multicurrency system has provided significant benefits . In particular, it fostered the re-monetization of the economy and financial re-intermediation, helped enforce fiscal discipline by precluding inflationary financing of the budget, and brought greater transparency in pricing and accounting after a long period of high inflation. As a result, the price level in U.S. dollars declined during 2009, while the economy started to recover.

The multicurrency system also poses a number of challenges . First, prices and wages are usually agreed and quoted in U.S. dollars, while South Africa is Zimbabwe’s main trading partner and country of origin of capital inflows. Movements in the U.S. dollar/rand exchange rate therefore have considerable effects on Zimbabwe’s competitiveness and international investment position. Second, shortages of small-denomination U.S. dollar banknotes and coins pose difficulties for retailers. Third, some politicians have expressed concern that loss of the national currency and seigniorage is an undesirable erosion of sovereignty and monetary independence.

The government considers the multicurrency monetary regime a temporary arrangement until 2012 at least . Therefore, the pros and cons of maintaining the multicurrency regime indefinitely are not discussed in this paper. Despite the remaining challenges (see above), the multicurrency regime could continue to operate with certain improvements until a new regime is chosen. The necessary improvements include aligning legislation, including the RBZ Act, with the prevailing practice of use of multiple currencies, making exchange controls more transparent, and facilitating the supply of coins, possibly with an agreement with South Africa.

This paper presents the pros and cons of various alternative monetary regimes to assist the government in making an informed choice of a future monetary regime (see Box II-1 ) . 4 This paper does not provide detailed guidance on transition issues from the multicurrency regime to various alternative regimes.

Various Alternatives for Monetary Reģimes

Full official dollarization

U.S. dollar as sole legal tender

Rand as sole legal tender (with or without CMA participation)

CMA participation with parallel circulation of the Zimbabwe dollar

Currency Board arrangement

Peg to the U.S. dollar

Peg to the rand without CMA participation

Intermediate and floating regimes

Conventional or crawling pegs or bands

Managed or free floating with a clearly defined nominal anchor

ch02ufig01

Existing regimes at end-April 2008 Number of countries

Citation: Departmental Papers 2010, 006; 10.5089/9781462309184.087.A001

  • Download Figure
  • Download figure as PowerPoint slide

Zimbabwe would need a monetary regime that provides an appropriate and credible nominal anchor and reduces the risk of destabilizing speculative attacks . These requirements are particularly important for Zimbabwe, which has monetary and fiscal institutions with low credibility due to a long history of poor governance, weak macroeconomic management, and a recent episode of unprecedented hyperinflation.

Benefits and Costs of Hard Peģs

All hard peg arrangements have common benefits and costs . Key benefits —low inflation, deeper financial intermediation, and ultimately better growth performance—would materialize only under certain credibility-enhancing institutional conditions. The latter include strong fiscal and monetary institutions that deliver fiscal discipline, and flexible goods and labor markets. 5

Key costs of hard pegs include loss of an autonomous monetary policy, possibly unfavorable exchange rate movements, and limited ability for the central bank to act as lender of last resort :

Loss of an autonomous monetary policy and the risk for unfavorable exchange rate movements would become main concerns if Zimbabwe adopted the currency of a country that did not meet the conditions for an optimal currency area. (That said, an autonomous monetary policy is beneficial only if supported by the appropriate institutional framework, which, considering previous hyperinflation, may take many years to establish in Zimbabwe.)

The central bank’s ability to act as lender of last resort and extend emergency liquidity assistance to the banking system would be subordinate to the primary objective of keeping the hard peg.

Anchor Currency

The key decision under any fixed exchange rate regime, including official dollarization, is the choice of the anchor currency . The benefits and costs of a specific currency will depend on whether Zimbabwe and the anchor-currency country meet the criteria for an optimal currency area:

Trade within the region . Countries that trade more with each other stand to gain more from a fixed exchange rate. The economic effects could be significant. 6

Shocks affecting the region . The cost of losing monetary independence is reduced if the countries are affected by symmetric shocks (that is, synchronized shocks). 7

Labor mobility within the region . This includes the physical ability to travel (visas, workers’ right, and so forth), lack of cultural barriers to free movement (such as different languages), and institutional arrangements. Labor mobility mitigates the cost of losing monetary independence, as it gives the unemployed an opportunity to move from a country in recession and apply for jobs in a growing country.

Fiscal transfers within the region . Fiscal transfers to countries affected by an adverse shock mitigate the cost of losing monetary independence.

In the case of Zimbabwe, the South African rand and the U.S. dollar have both been considered as possible anchor currencies . An assessment based on the four above criteria suggests the rand has an advantage relative to the U.S. dollar from the perspective of trade integration, labor mobility, and potential fiscal transfers, while evidence is mixed on whether shocks are synchronized between Zimbabwe and South Africa.

South Africa is Zimbabwe’s dominant trading partner . About 40 percent of Zimbabwe’s imports originate from South Africa and about 25 percent of Zimbabwe’s exports are delivered to South Africa ( Figure II—I ). Zimbabwe’s trade with the United States is only a small share of total imports and exports. Because of the significance of South Africa, a hard peg to the rand would reduce trading costs and support further trade integration between the two countries. If Zimbabwe joined the South African Customs Union (SACU), a hard peg to the rand would reinforce economic integration with South Africa and the countries whose currencies are pegged to the rand in part owing to the absence of exchange rate fluctuations. 8 This, in turn, would contribute to lower real effective exchange rate volatility.

Figure II-1.

Geoģraphical Distribution of Zimbabwe’s Imports and Exports, Averages 2000-08

The synchronization of two types of shocks is examined . First, correlations between disturbances to output are analyzed. Second, comovements of terms of trade are studied.

Correlation of disturbances to output ( Box II—2 ) . A statistical analysis of underlying output disturbances indicates that shocks to Zimbabwe’s economy have not been correlated with those to the United States’ economy. Evidence is mixed for correlations of Zimbabwe’s output shocks with those for South Africa. No statistically significant correlation of shocks to output appears for the entire period under review (1977-2000). In the 1980s, Zimbabwe benefited from rapid post-independence growth, while South Africa under the apartheid government was subject to international sanctions. However, South Africa and Zimbabwe appear to have had relatively synchronized shocks during the 1990s, when both countries enjoyed a period of relative economic stability.

Correlations of terms of trade ( Box II—3 ) . Zimbabwe’s terms of trade movements were not synchronized either with the United States or South Africa during 1986—2008. No statistically significant correlation appears between Zimbabwe’s and United States’ terms of trade. The correlation between Zimbabwe’s and South Africa’s terms of trade is negative and statistically significant. Although both Zimbabwe and South Africa are major mineral-exporting countries, agricultural exports were more important for Zimbabwe during the 1980s and 1990s. In fact, agriculture (dominated by tobacco) made up more than 40 percent of Zimbabwe’s export earnings during the 1980s and the 1990s, while agricultural products represented a small share of South Africa’s export. Zimbabwe’s agricultural exports have declined rapidly since the late 1990s, which is likely to make Zimbabwe’s and South Africa’s terms of trade more synchronized.

Labor mobility

Observed actual emigration from Zimbabwe to South Africa is a crucial safety valve, mitigating the social and humanitarian costs of Zimbabwe’s economic problems . Zimbabwe’s unemployed have been moving to South Africa for more than 10 years. A recent study estimates that about one million Zimbabweans lived in South Africa by the end of 2007. 9 The Zimbabwe-born population is estimated at about 12 million with about 7.5 million in the working-age group of 15—64 years. This suggests that more than 10 percent of the working-age population has moved to South Africa. Most emigrants entered South Africa illegally without the required papers. To regularize an increasingly difficult situation and improve control over migration, South Africa removed visa requirements for Zimbabwean’s in April 2009. Zimbabweans are now allowed to enter South Africa for up to 90 days and seek temporary work on a visitor’s permit. While there is no statistical information on emigration to the United States, it is clearly much more modest.

Shocks to Zimbabwe’s Economy—A Statistical Analysis

To what extent are shocks to Zimbabwe’s economy correlated to shocks affecting South Africa and the United States? A statistical three-step approach used by Bayoumi and Ostry (1994) and Wang et al. (2007) was applied to answer this question.

First , a unit root (Augmented Dickey Fuller) test was carried out on the time series data of the natural log of per capita real GDP for Zimbabwe, South Africa, and the United States for the period 1974𠀓2004. The test confirmed that the time series are integrated of order 1. As a result, the next step used the first difference of the per capita real GDP.

Second , for each country, the change in the natural log of per capita real GDP was regressed upon its first to fourth lags, as described in the following equation:

where ( y l ) t is the natural log of per capita real GDP at period t and µ t is an error term, capturing the deviations of per capita real GDP from the estimated long-run trend. The residuals from these regressions are estimates of the underlying disturbances affecting each country.

Third , the correlation of the residuals was estimated. If the correlation is positive and significant, we conclude that the countries are affected by symmetric shocks, but a negative and/or insignificant correlation is the result of asymmetric shocks.

The estimates indicate that shocks to Zimbabwe’s economy have been asymmetric and uncorrelated to shocks affecting South Africa or the United States during the period 1977—2000. Estimated parameters are low and do not refute the null hypothesis of no correlation. However, for a shorter period covering 1990—98, Zimbabwe and South Africa seem to have been affected by symmetric shocks, as shown by a relatively high correlation.

Correlation of Underlying Disturbances, 1977-2000

* Note: indicates that the correlation is significantly different from zero at the 10 percent level.

1977-2000 1990-1998 South Africa 0.11 0.61 United States -0.18 -0.26
Zimbabwe

Terms-of-Trade—A Statistical Analysis

zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

Terms of Trade, 1985-2008 (1985 = 100)

zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

Terms of Trade, 1986-2008

(Annual percentage change)

Correlation of Changes in Terms-of-Trade, 1986-2008

** indicates that the correlation is significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level.

1986-2008 South Africa -0.53 United States 0.26
Zimbabwe

Fiscal transfers

Fiscal transfers from abroad would mitigate the cost of losing monetary independence . The cost would be reduced, if more fiscal resources became available from abroad in case of a negative shock to Zimbabwe’s economy. At present, there are no automatic fiscal transfers between South Africa and Zimbabwe. However, Zimbabwe could potentially join SACU, which as an organization has a revenue-sharing formula favoring poorer member countries. SACU revenue sharing could, therefore, mitigate a negative shock to Zimbabwe’s economy in case of an idiosyncratic shock to its economy. 10

Full Official Dollarization

Compared with hard pegs, full official dollarization has additional benefits and costs . 11

Given the current widespread dollarization and the nonfunctionality of the Zimbabwe dollar, full official dollarization would be the easiest option to implement in the near term operationally and institutionally.

If credible, dollarization eliminates the risk of future currency crises (in this respect, dollarization is a stronger arrangement than a currency board), thereby reducing market-determined interest rate spreads over the interest rates of the country whose currency is adopted. Credibility can be boosted by political backing of the country whose currency is adopted and an agreement on seigniorage sharing.

By definitely rejecting the possibility of inflationary finance, dollarization may also strengthen fiscal policy institutions.

Dollarization would reduce costs of international transactions with the country whose currency is adopted (in this respect, dollarization has more advantages than a currency board arrangement), thereby promoting trade and financial integration.

The loss of seigniorage from issuing domestic currency. This cost can be eliminated or reduced if there is agreement on sharing seigniorage with the country whose currency is adopted as legal tender.

Even if a national currency is re-introduced at some stage, de facto widespread dollarization will most likely persist.

For Zimbabwe, among potential legal tender currencies, the U.S. dollar and the rand have clear advantages relative to other currencies given the established practice . In addition to the previous discussion, full official dollarization with the dollar as sole legal tender brings the following advantages:

The dollar circulates more widely in Zimbabwe than any other foreign currency, pricing and accounting are predominantly undertaken in dollars, and the payments systems function in U.S. dollars. All these factors would facilitate a smoother transition to full official dollarization with the U.S. dollar as sole legal tender.

The United States does not impose capital account restrictions, which would facilitate use of U.S. dollars in cash and noncash transactions. However, shipping U.S. dollar coins is cost-prohibitive, which would mean that coins may need to be minted domestically, provided strong accountability and international reserve backing arrangements could be put in place (see the example of Ecuador, Appendix II—1 ).

The United States has deeper and more developed financial markets, potentially making it easier for the government and the private sector to benefit from an eventual reduction in interest rate spreads.

The advantages of the rand as the anchor currency presented in the previous discussion remain valid in full official dollarization with the rand as sole legal tender . Any additional advantages from this option can be derived only through the Common Monetary Area (CMA) membership (which is possible without reintroducing the Zimbabwe dollar) or a bilateral agreement on relaxation of South Africa’s restrictions on exportation of banknotes and coins:

Zimbabwe and South Africa can potentially agree on sharing seigniorage similarly to the existing arrangements of South Africa with Lesotho and Namibia in the context of the CMA. The ensuing political backing of South Africa would strengthen the credibility of the new monetary regime in Zimbabwe.

The rand would also offer more appropriate small denominations, and banknote and coin handling costs would be lower than with the U.S. dollar. Absent CMA membership, this advantage can be realized through a bilateral agreement with South Africa.

CMA Membership with Parallel Circulation of the Zimbabwe Dollar

Under CMA membership with reintroduction of the Zimbabwe dollar, domestic currency would circulate alongside the anchor currency at a one-to-one parity, and reserve money would be fully backed by international reserves in a currency board arrangement . Similar monetary frameworks have been adopted by Lesotho and Namibia ( Appendix II—2 ).

The initial impact of Zimbabwe’s CMA membership would most likely be small on the rest of the CMA . Zimbabwe’s GDP was less than 2 percent of the CMA total in 2009 and broad money and stock market capitalization were less than 1 percent of the corresponding CMA total at the end of December 2009 ( Table II—1 ).

Selected Economic Data for CMA and Zimbabwe (In billions of U.S. dollars)

CMA South Africa Zimbabwe Nominal GDP, 2009 291.0 277.4 4.4 Broad money, end-December 2009 278.6 272.6 1.3 Stockmarket capitalization, end-December 2009 799.0 about 4

A model by Debrun, Masson, and Patillo ( 2005 and 2009 ) has been calibrated to estimate possible gains to Zimbabwe from CMA membership ( Box II—4 ) . 12 The exercise compares CMA membership with a currency regime with some scope for monetary policy discretion (that is, CMA membership is not compared with the existing multicurrency system in place since early 2009). The model predicts that Zimbabwe would gain significantly from CMA membership, while the welfare of existing CMA members would fall marginally. Most of the gain for Zimbabwe would come from increased fiscal discipline. In other words, the model predicts that CMA membership is better than an independent currency, as Zimbabwe would benefit from the credibility of the CMA framework.

The CMA was established to promote “sustained economic development” of its members—currently Lesotho, Namibia, Swaziland, and South Africa—and to “encourage the advancement of the less developed members of the Common Monetary Area.” 13 If Zimbabwe determined that the benefits of promoting the use of the rand outweighed those of the U.S. dollar, joining the CMA and reintroducing the local currency would have several added benefits, but also at certain added costs. 14

How Larģe are the Gains from CMA Membership?

The model by Debrun, Masson and Patillo ( 2005 , 2009 ) offers a framework to quantify gains from CMA membership. In the model, countries that consider entering a monetary union differ along three dimensions: size, distortions affecting fiscal policy, and random supply shocks. The model features the classic Barro-Gordon inflationary bias: monetary authorities want to increase output through unexpected increases in inflation, but the public anticipates the central bank’s actions and the resulting higher level of inflation. In a monetary union, the common central bank faces a steeper Phillips curve as it receives a lower benefit from any particular monetary injection. The slope of the new Phillips curve is a function of trade linkages across member states.

In the model there are three sources of net welfare gains from membership in a currency union:

Monetary externality : This externality results from lack of policy coordination. With independent currencies, countries have an incentive to engage in beggar-thy-neighbor policies which result in excessive inflation. The higher the intensity of trade linkages across member countries, the greater the gains—in terms of lower inflation—stemming from monetary unification.

Fiscal externality : Government spending can be financed by the inflation tax or through taxation. However, each government loses revenues through inefficiencies (for example, tax collection costs) or by spending on socially detrimental projects (for example, corruption). If financing needs are too high to cover both socially beneficial spending and institutional deadweight loss, the inflation rate will be positive. Gains from unification arise from the fact that the level of inflation now reflects the average level of financing needs across members. Countries joining a union with less profligate members will benefit from the fiscal restraints of their counterparts.

Terms-of-trade asymmetry : A potential loss of welfare may arise from the fact that the common central bank can modify policy only imperfectly in response to country-specific shocks.

Net Welfare Gains from Zimbabwe CMA Membership

(in percent of own GDP, unless otherwise indicated)

Lesotho -0.28 Namibia -0.27 South Africa -0.35 Swaziland -0.35 Total (percent of CMA GDP) -0.35 Monetary Total externality Fiscal externality TOT asymmetry Zimbabwe 24.2 4.5 20.9 -0.6

The model is calibrated to Zimbabwe and current CMA members. It predicts that existing members’ welfare would fall marginally, by about ⅓ of 1 percent of CMA GDP. Zimbabwe, however, would gain over 24 percent of GDP with most of the gain stemming from the fiscal externality.

A word of caution: this result is based on very strong assumptions about the value of calibrated parameters and functioning of monetary and fiscal policy. In addition, the exercise compares CMA membership to monetary policy with an independent and free-floating currency, though the multicurrency system has been in place since early 2009.

Additional advantages

Zimbabwe would be able to issue its own currency under currency board rules (see below).

Zimbabwe would benefit from stronger confidence in its monetary regime due to external discipline that CMA membership would provide.

Zimbabwe would receive seigniorage for its use of the rand, and it would be able to derive its own seigniorage from issuance of local currency ( Box II—5 ).

Institutions in the public and private sector in CMA member countries, subject to relevant financial laws and policies applicable to counterparts in South Africa, have the right of access to the South African capital and money markets.

The central banks and authorized dealers in foreign exchange in CMA member countries have access to the foreign exchange market in South Africa.

There are no restrictions on the transfers of rand funds within the CMA whether for current or capital account purposes, except for optional domestic asset requirements for domestic financial institutions.

While the Reserve Bank of South Africa would effectively determine the monetary policy of Zimbabwe, the arrangements explicitly provide for policy consultation.

Additional disadvantages

Adoption of the regime requires agreement with CMA members, which may be difficult or time-consuming to obtain.

Zimbabwe would be subject to common CMA exchange controls vis-à-vis the rest of the world, which could raise significant transition issues given more liberal capital account controls in Zimbabwe and the current market preference for the U.S. dollar in Zimbabwe ( Box II—6 ).

If the Zimbabwe government gained access to capital markets, the risk of its borrowing could be potentially mispriced and fiscal discipline weakened due to a possible (unjustified) market perception that Zimbabwe could be bailed out by other CMA members. (The existing CMA framework does not allow for such a bailout).

Sharing of Seiģnioraģe within the CMA

Seigniorage for the use of the rand is calculated as follows:

s = (2/3)*(i bondyield )*(cu R ), where

i bondyield = annual yield on most recently issued long-term South African government stock

cu R = an estimate of the volume of rand in circulation in Zimbabwe

The 2/3 is a compromise to take account of the estimated interest earned by a portfolio invested in both long-term and short-term assets in the CMA area.

As an example, assuming average bank deposits of US$1,350 million in 2010 and households holding currency equal to 20 percent of total bank deposits, the potential amount of currency in circulation is estimated at US$270 million for 2010. If all currency was denominated in rand and the average bond yield is assumed to be 8.5 percent, the CMA revenue-sharing formula would allocate about US$15 million ((2/3)*0.085*US$270 million) to Zimbabwe in 2010.

Elements of Exchange Controls

CMA Zimbabwe Residents may hold at most R4 million in foreign currency deposits with commercial banks. No limits on holdings of foreign currency deposits in USD, ZAR, EUR, GBP, and the Botswana Pula. Residents need prior approval to contract loans with non-residents. Residents can freely contract loans with non-residents for amounts up to US$5 million. Prior approval is requested for the payment of amortization of loans, depreciation of direct investments, and remittances of profits and dividends. Prior approval is requested for the payment of interest and amortization of loans, if the amount exceeds US$1.5 million. Payments of dividends, profits, and income from capital as well as payments of depreciation of direct investments do not need prior approval.

Currency Board Arranģement

Zimbabwe could issue its own currency as sole legal tender under currency board rules . It would buy or sell its currency in response to market demand in exchange for foreign currency at a legislatively fixed exchange rate, thus automatically insuring 100 percent foreign reserve asset backing. The currency board authority could not borrow, lend, or buy domestic assets other than from capital (or other surpluses). 15

A currency board imposes as much discipline on the monetary authority as does dollarization, provided currency board rules are clearly defined and implemented in practice.

Under a currency board, a country issues a national currency (a national symbol desired by many countries) and receives associated seigniorage revenue.

Maintenance of a stock of fit notes and coins would be easier than with a foreign currency.

Significant time might be needed to garner political support for adopting central bank and fiscal responsibility legislation consistent with international best practice.

Given a long history of governance problems at the RBZ and high inflation, the credibility of a currency board arrangement without externally imposed safeguards could be low even if new central bank and fiscal legislation were fully compliant with international best practice. Existing banking system vulnerabilities, if not addressed, would further undermine the credibility of a currency board.

Currency boards are vulnerable to speculative currency attacks because they only guarantee 100 percent reserve coverage of base money, and a large share of banking deposits is not covered. Considering the history of Zimbabwe, speculative currency attacks would most likely represent a major challenge and the currency board could become a succession of fixed but adjustable pegs. 16

The advantages and disadvantages of the U.S. dollar and the rand as anchor currency are the same as presented for fixed exchange rate regimes in the previous discussion.

  • Intermediate and Fully Flexible Exchange Rate Reģimes

Other options include regimes that could vary from conventionally fixed or adjustable pegs/bands, to crawling pegs/bands, to managed floating or freely floating exchange rates . These monetary policy regimes would increase the degree of monetary policy autonomy. A monetary policy regime without an exchange rate anchor (that is, managed or free floating) requires an explicit and clearly understood alternative nominal anchor to guide monetary policy and to provide a basis for central bank credibility and accountability. Best practice for market-determined exchange rate regimes is “inflation targeting” or, more properly, “inflation forecast targeting.” This is the regime adopted by the Reserve Bank of South Africa. In the medium term, Zimbabwe will face significant challenges in implementing intermediate or fully flexible exchange rate regimes because of significant credibility problems associated with the past history of high inflation, governance problems at the RBZ, and fiscal dominance, as well as a low level of financial development and significant weaknesses in statistical databases (both precluding reliable monitoring and forecasting of macroeconomic indicators).

CMA membership would bring significant benefits in terms of regional trade and financial integration and seigniorage sharing . Zimbabwe would also gain from the credibility of a well-established monetary framework while re-introducing its national currency. However, transition challenges, including the requirement to adopt South Africa’s more restrictive capital account controls and to promote a wider circulation of the rand, would need to be addressed.

Full official dollarization with the U.S. dollar as sole legal tender would be the most straightforward option to implement both operationally and institutionally in the near term, as the U.S. dollar has already become the dominant currency in the multicurrency system . However, beyond the short term, there is a disadvantage of belonging to a currency area which is not optimal for Zimbabwe.

A currency board arrangement with the Zimbabwe dollar as sole legal tender would allow the country to collect the full amount of seigniorage, provided de facto dollarization declines, and reassert full sovereignty over the currency and exchange control issues . However, it would be a significant challenge to make this framework credible even if all strict institutional preconditions for the establishment of the currency board are put in place and enacted. The credibility of the currency board could be boosted by more than 100 percent coverage of base money, which would involve significant fiscal costs.

Intermediate and flexible exchange rate arrangements would increase the degree of monetary policy autonomy, but in the absence of a relatively long track record of sound policy implementation under a well established credible institutional framework such regimes could become inherently unstable .

  • Appendix II-1 Ecuador’s Experience with Transition to Full Official Dollarization

There are several examples of full official dollarization . Panama adopted the U.S. dollar as legal tender in 1904 without retaining a central bank ( Moreno-Villaz, 2005 ). El Salvador , which had a history of low inflation, fully dollarized in 2001, in order to achieve lower interest rate spreads and facilitate closer integration with international financial markets. Other countries and territories, including East Timor, Montenegro , and Kosovo , also operate dollarized monetary regimes. This appendix presents the experience of Ecuador in its transition to full official dollarization, which was orderly and well designed ( IMF, 2000 ). The analysis of subsequent economic difficulties facing Ecuador goes beyond the scope of this paper.

Transition to New Leģal Tender

Following the adoption of a comprehensive stabilization package in early 2000, a number of steps were implemented in Ecuador to adopt the U.S. dollar as legal tender :

A prohibition on local currency issue (except as fully backed coins).

An announcement of a fixed conversion rate vis-à-vis the U.S. dollar, which was close to a market exchange rate. The central bank had enough gross official reserves to buy back local currency banknotes and back the remainder of reserve money which is translated into U.S. dollars at the preannounced exchange rate.

An obligation of the central bank to exchange local currency for U.S. dollars at the preannounced exchange rate and retire from circulation all purchased local currency banknotes.

An obligation of all economic agents to translate their accounts into U.S. dollars.

A shift to all budget payments in U.S. dollars at the outset of dollarization and tax collection exclusively in U.S. dollars by the end of the transition period.

Translation of all local currency-denominated loans and deposits in the banking system into U.S. dollars with a one-time mandated reduction in nominal interest rates.

Institutional Chanģes

Central bank.

Ecuador’s central bank retained a number of functions following dollarization in part owing to significant weaknesses in commercial banks, which would have prevented an effective operation of a fully private monetary system such as the one in Panama :

Liquidity support (through U.S. dollar-denominated liquidity facilities partly financed by international financial institutions); participation in money markets; and, at the initial stage of dollarization, market making in the government securities market.

Fiscal agent.

Macroeconomic analysis and research.

Financial stability and lender of last resort function to the extent of available foreign currency reserves.

Payment system services.

Cash handling.

Figure II -1.1.

Ecuador: Banking System Deposits

(Millions of US dollars)

Financial system

In Ecuador, dollarization has increased confidence in the banking system and has helped financial re-intermediation . Deposits in the banking system increased from US$1.9 billion in 1999 to over US$4 billion in 2001, strengthening the liquidity of the banking system and its lending capacity.

Budget and budgetary agencies

Dollarization in Ecuador had significant implications for fiscal operations :

All tax obligations and assessments were required to be made in U.S. dollars and settled either in U.S. dollars or local currency during the transition period and only in U.S. dollars thereafter.

All expenditures items were implemented in U.S. dollars at the outset of dollarization.

Fiscal adjustment mainly occurred on the revenue side with an improvement in revenue collection by 2 percent of GDP during the first year of dollarization.

Ecuador: Summary of Consolidated Nonfinancial Public Sector Operations

(In percent of GDP)

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Total revenue 19.1 22.5 27.6 24.7 25.9 Petroleum 3.9 6.2 9.2 6.4 5.7 Non-petroleum 15.1 15.6 17.6 17.8 19.3 Operating surplus of 0.1 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.9 public enterprises Total expenditure 24.1 27.1 26.5 25.1 25.1 Overall surplus or deficit (-) -5.0 -4.6 1.0 -0.5 1.0

Appendix II-2. CMA Institutional Framework 17

Currency Arrangements . Article 2 of the CMA (Multilateral) Agreement gives the three small member countries—Lesotho, Namibia, and Swaziland (LNS)—the right to issue national currencies, and their bilateral agreements with South Africa define principles of bilateral relations with South Africa. The local currencies issued by the three members are legal tender only in their own countries. The South African rand, however, is legal tender throughout the CMA. The bilateral agreements also require the LNS countries to permit authorized dealers within their territories to convert, at par, notes issued by their central banks or the South African Reserve Bank without restriction and subject only to normal handling charges.

Under the Lesotho-South Africa and Namibia-South Africa bilateral agreements, the central banks of Lesotho and Namibia are required to maintain foreign reserves at least equivalent to the total amount of local currencies they issue . Such reserves may comprise the central bank’s holdings of rand balances, the rand currency the central bank holds in a Special Rand Deposit Account with the SARB, South African government stock (up to a certain proportion of total reserves), and investments in the Corporation for Public Deposit in South Africa.

Movement of Funds within the CMA . Under the terms of the CMA Agreement (Article 3), no restrictions can be imposed on the transfer of funds, whether for current or capital transactions, to or from any member country. The only exceptions are the member countries’ investment or liquidity requirements for financial institutions. The small member countries view the investment and liquidity requirements as a measure of savings mobilization for development purposes. The regulations requiring the investment of funds by financial institutions in domestic securities or credits to local businesses or individuals are, in effect, minimum local asset requirements. These regulations are meant to address the concern of the three small, less developed CMA members that funds generated in their territories and deposited with local financial institutions tended to flow to the more developed capital markets of South Africa.

Access to South African Financial Markets . The CMA Agreement gives the three small member countries access to the South African capital and money markets, but only through prescribed investments or approved securities that can be held by financial institutions in South Africa, in accordance with prudential regulations in the LNS countries. The terms and timing of such issues are subject to consultation and agreement with the South African government, and the issues have the same rating as South African municipal bonds.

As for the short-term money markets, there are no regular arrangements for the taking up in South Africa of treasury bills issued by the LNS countries. However, the CMA Agreement recognizes the right of the other member countries, in special circumstances, to enter into bilateral negotiations with South Africa to obtain temporary central bank credit.

Gold and Foreign Exchange Transactions . Although the LNS countries have the right to authorize foreign transactions of local origin, and are responsible for doing so, the CMA Agreement (Article 5) requires their exchange control regulations to be—in all material aspects—similar to those in effect in South Africa ( Box II—2.1 ). Gold and foreign exchange receipts of residents are subject to a surrender requirement. There are no exchange restrictions on current international transactions and for nonresidents.

Compensation Payments . South Africa compensates Lesotho and Namibia for forgone seigniorage. Compensation is based on a formula equal to the product of (i) two thirds of the annual yield on the most recently issued long-term South African government stock and (ii) the volume of rands estimated in circulation in the member country concerned. The ratio of two-thirds was established on the assumption that it approximated the yield of a portfolio of reserve assets comprising both long-term and short-term maturities, assuming the average yield would be less than the full long-term yield.

Consultation and Other Provisions . To facilitate implementation of the CMA Agreement, the member countries have established a commission in which each of them has one representative (along with advisors as needed). The commission holds regular consultations—at least once a year—to reconcile the interests of member countries on common issues pertaining to monetary and foreign exchange policies. It also convenes at other times at the request of a member country. Article 9 of the CMA Agreement provides for establishment of a tribunal to arbitrate disputes that might arise between member countries regarding the interpretation or application of the agreement.

Elements of Exchanģe Controls in South Africa

Residents may hold at most R4 million in foreign currency deposits with commercial banks.

Residents need prior approval to contract loans with nonresidents.

Prior approval is requested for the payment of amortization of loans, depreciation of direct investments, and remittances of profits and dividends.

Residents and nonresidents are allowed to export rand-denominated banknotes up to R5,000.

From outside the CMA area, residents and nonresidents are allowed to import rand-denominated banknotes only up to R5,000.

  • Appendix II-3. The Debrun, Masson, and Pattillo Model

The Debrun, Masson and Patillo (2009) model is based on the following equations:

Phillips curve with regional spillovers Government budget constraint (no debt) Government’s utility function Trade-off between output and inflation variability with η>0 Phillips curve faced by the common central bank for each member of M Key variables and parameters π Inflation rate in country . A superscript “e” designates a rationally expected value. Logarithm of output in country . Logarithm of the natural level of output at zero taxation. Tax revenues in percent of output. Marginal effect of monetary policy in country on output in country . Terms of trade shock (zero-mean, transitory, and with finite variance). Socially beneficial government expenditure in percent of output. Inflation tax base in percent of output. Permanent nontax revenue from natural resource endowment in percent of output. Funds diverted from socially beneficial government expenditure in percent of output. Relative preference for output stability against inflation stability.
Supranational monetary policy

The calibration of the main parameters is as follows:

Parameter Country variation Definition Calibration Financing needs Country-specific Wasteful and socially beneficial spending “Ideal” revenues estimated as a function of macroeconomic variables and governance μ Common Captures the base for the inflation tax Average broad money to GDP for SSA, 1994-2005 c Common Captures effect of monetary surprises on output Use estimates of Phillips curve for Africa Welfare parameters Common Utility-function parameters Estimated from model-derived relationships θ Country-specific Trade intensity Exports of country i to j as ratio to GDP η Common Captures trade-off between variability of inflation and variability of output Proportional to the ratio between standard deviation of terms of trade shocks and inflation shocks Shock asymmetry Country-specific Correlation of terms-of-trade shocks

Details are available in the Debrun, Masson and Patillo paper.

Chapter 3. Assessing Competitiveness and External Sustainability in Zimbabwe 18

  • Introduction

After many years of falling output and hyperinflation, Zimbabwe has been experiencing a fragile recovery since early 2009. During its decade-long economic downturn, Zimbabwe’s external position deteriorated sharply, with the country unable to meet many of its external obligations and accumulating arrears. The jump start in growth has so far been consumption-led, but Zimbabwe’s export sector, in particular mining, could potentially recover quickly and provide much needed fiscal revenues to a cash-strapped government with large external obligations.

In the staff’s medium-term baseline projection (on current policies), Zimbabwe continues to run large current account deficits financed by short-term and volatile capital inflows and accumulation of arrears. Zimbabwe is in debt distress: external debt—of which about 64 percent corresponds to external arrears—is projected to be about 151 percent of GDP by 2015 ( Table III—1 ).

Zimbabwe: Selected Economic Indicators, 2008-15

1/ In constant 2009 prices.

2/ For 2008, annual average January-September 2008.

3/ Zimbabwe dollar values converted into U.S. dollars at the UN exchange rate at the end of 2008.

4/ Gross official reserves as reported by the authorities are adjusted for encumbered deposits, securities, banks’ Real Time Gross Settlement accounts, and required statutory reserves.

5/ Includes arrears and amounts for unidentified financing.

Baseline 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Real GDP growth (annual percent change) -14.5 4.0 2.2 0.0 1.0 1.8 2.0 2.0 Nominal GDP (US$ millions) 3,929 4,397 5,144 5,488 5,845 6,159 6,517 6,892 Consumer price inflation (annual percent change) 6E+10 6.5 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 Central government (percent of GDP, measured in US$) Revenue and grants 3.4 22.2 26.1 26.8 26.4 26.3 26.3 26.3 Expenditure and net lending 6.5 25.0 33.7 30.4 31.7 32.0 32.0 32.0 : Cash expenditure and net lending 3.1 20.9 30.7 26.9 26.4 26.3 26.3 26.3 Employment Costs 1.5 11.8 17.8 19.7 21.2 21.0 21.1 21.1 Overall balance (including quasi-fiscal activity) -32.1 -3.3 -7.6 -3.6 -5.3 -5.7 -5.7 -5.7 Cash balance 0.3 1.2 -4.5 -0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Money and credit (US$ millions) Broad money (M3) 314 1,276 1,511 Domestic credit 140 602 1,048 : credit to the private sector 140 684 1,055 Balance of payments (percent of GDP) Current account balance (excluding official transfers) -24.0 -30.1 -23.0 -13.2 -13.6 -13.6 -13.6 -13.3 Overall balance -15.9 0.7 -14.1 -8.4 -7.6 -5.8 -5.7 -5.5 Official reserves Gross official reserves (US$ millions;end-of-period) 6 312 114 114 114 115 115 115 Gross official reserves (months of imports of goods and services) 0.0 1.0 0.3 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 Total external debt (percent of GDP; end-of-period) 147.5 162.5 149.0 148.3 149.0 150.5 150.9 151.3
Estimated Projected

This paper raises three inter-related questions relevant for the analysis of external stability in the context of Zimbabwe. First, to what extent can the country increase exports, including from mining, and attract foreign financing in the medium term to strengthen its balance of payments position?

Second, what is the current stock of Zimbabwe’s net foreign assets, including the net present value (NPV) of future mineral exports? And third, is it possible to bring part of mineral revenues forward to settle external payments arrears and achieve a sustainable balance of payments position?

The summary of the findings is as follows:

The initial conditions in terms of competitiveness are unfavorable for exports and foreign and domestic investments, making it difficult to achieve a rapid increase in exports and FDI, including in mining. Indeed, Zimbabwe performs poorly in terms of competitiveness whether it is measured by governance (including rule of law, property centers, and corruption), investment climate (including enforcement of property right and infrastructure), or price indicators.

At the end of 2009, Zimbabwe’s net foreign asset position (NFA) was significantly negative. Including the estimated NPV of future mineral receipts under an optimistic scenario in which the competitiveness issues mentioned above are addressed, the NFA position is negative in the order of -63 percent of GDP. This reflects a large debt overhang and infrastructure and regulatory bottlenecks that slow the pace of extracting gold and platinum—key high-value minerals in Zimbabwe—and diamonds. Just maintaining this high level of the negative NFA would require generating non-mineral primary external current account surpluses whereas this balance now stands at more than -35 percent of GDP. Closing such a large gap without debt relief is not feasible in the foreseeable future, even if the challenges with competitiveness and the business climate are addressed without further delays.

The present value of the government in-take from mineral resource wealth (based on the current tax system) was estimated at 42 percent of GDP at the end of 2009. This amount is significantly smaller than the size of Zimbabwe’s arrears on external public and publicly guaranteed debt (104 percent of GDP). This suggests that bringing forward resource revenues would not provide sufficient financial resources to reduce gross debt, eliminate arrears, or solve the problem of public debt overhang.

Only a combination of sound policies and debt relief would help achieve external and growth sustainability and increase benefits associated with mineral wealth by accelerating the pace of extraction and providing access to fresh foreign financing at a lower cost.

These findings are subject to important caveats. Significant uncertainty exists regarding proven mineral reserves and possible extraction rates in the foreseeable future, as well as extraction costs and investment requirements. Because of these limitations, estimates are tentative. That said, the orders of magnitudes of estimates appear robust for plausible changes in assumptions.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. We first describe recent balance of payments developments before reviewing indicators of competitiveness in Zimbabwe in the second section. The last section presents measures of Zimbabwe’s external position and an assessment of the economy’s external sustainability.

  • External Sector: Recent Developments

Zimbabwe’s external position is precarious. The current account has been in deficit for the past decade. Exports have stagnated over the past 10 years on account of the disruptive economic environment. Investment in key export sectors is handicapped by inadequate infrastructure, high operational costs are exacerbated by wage pressures, and the poor business climate makes Zimbabwe less attractive to investors. Agriculture’s share in exports has fallen substantially as continued land redistribution has contributed to large declines in production ( Figure III—I ). Higher food and fuel prices in 2008, and increases in volumes of donor-financed humanitarian aid, led to a significant rise in imports. Moreover, the tentative 2009 recovery increased import demand, boosted by public spending and the expansion of credit to the private sector ( Figure III—I ). Staff estimate that in 2009 the current account deficit reached 30 percent of GDP and external debt rose to US$7.1 billion (162 percent of GDP), with external arrears accounting for about 64 percent of external debt. 19 Dependence on donor aid has also increased significantly, with current and capital transfers through NGOs estimated at 12 percent of GDP in 2009. The current account deficit, excluding transfers through NGOs, amounted to 41 percent of GDP in 2009.

Figure III-1.

Zimbabwe: Exports and Imports of Goods, 2000-2009

Zimbabwe faces significant capital account vulnerabilities. Given Zimbabwe’s large current account deficit and its inability to meet its external financial obligations, external arrears account for a large portion of its external financing ( Figure III—2 ). Moreover, Zimbabwe has been unable to attract large long-term capital flows, relying instead on short-term flows which are more vulnerable to sudden stops. 20 More recently, the government has started converting a one-time SDR allocation (US$410 million) to finance budgetary expenditures, which is contributing to a rapid depletion of international reserves. As a result, Zimbabwe is particularly vulnerable to adverse shocks to its balance of payments. In early 2010, increased uncertainty about indigenization legislation slowed capital inflows and deteriorated investors’ confidence, which has added further pressure to the already vulnerable external position.

Figure III-2.

Zimbabwe: External Financing, 2005 - 2009

  • Measurinģ and Assessing Zimbabwe’s Competitiveness

This section analyzes non-price measures of Zimbabwe’s structural competitiveness and shows that Zimbabwe is one of the worst performers relative to comparator countries. An analysis of non-price measures could help in assessing a country’s relative competitiveness and identify areas where reforms are most needed to address binding constraints on growth. We consider the most widely used indicators: (i) the Global Competitiveness Index of the World Economic Forum; (ii) the World Governance Indicators of the World Bank; (iii) the Doing Business Report indicators of the World Bank; and (iv) the Corruption Perception Index of Transparency International. In addition, we also look at other measures of competitiveness, such as business startup costs, wages, and access to basic infrastructure.

Zimbabwe performed poorly on structural competitiveness indicators across all dimensions relative to comparator countries, which means it is less competitive in the global market place. Table III—2 provides a summary of the relative position of Zimbabwe compared with PRGT-eligible and HIPC countries. According to the Global Competitiveness Index , which captures the set of policies, institutions and factors that determine the level of productivity of a country, Zimbabwe ranks 132 among 133 countries surveyed. The World Governance Indicators reflect survey opinions across several dimensions: voice and accountability, political stability, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption. Again, Zimbabwe’s score fell well below the average scores in PRGT-eligible and HIPC countries across all dimensions, with regulatory quality and rule of law having the lowest scores ( Figure III—3 ). The World Bank’s Doing Business Report ranks Zimbabwe 159 th out of 183 countries studied. By component, although Zimbabwe has done better than most of its comparator countries in the areas of registering property and enforcing contracts, it has done worse than most countries in terms of starting a business, dealing with construction permits, getting credit, protecting investors, paying taxes, and closing a business. Finally, Zimbabwe is perceived to have more corruption relative to comparator groups.

Summary Indicators of Structural Competitiveness

Indicator Zimbabwe PRGT HIPC Range of values Interpretation Global Competitiveness Index 2.8 3.5 3.4 1.0-7.0 higher value is better World Governance Indicators -1.7 -0.5 -0.8 -2.5 - +2.5 higher value is better Ease of Doing Business 159.0 125.1 146.1 1-183 lower ranking is better Corruption Perception Index 2.2 2.7 2.5 0-10.0 higher value is better

Figure III-3.

Zimbabwe: Components of World Governance Indicators, 2008

Business costs in Zimbabwe are higher relative to comparator countries. Table III—3 shows that it takes more time and costs to start a business in Zimbabwe compared with other countries in the region. Indicators of wage costs are also higher compared to most countries in the SSA region ( Figure III—4 ). Finally, the level of access to most basic infrastructure in Zimbabwe (for 2008) falls between those in low-income and lower middle-income countries ( Table III—4 ), except for the proportion of telephone subscribers to the population, which is lower than the average in low-income countries. Infrastructure, however, has recently deteriorated, and related services have declined in Zimbabwe.

Zimbabwe: Starting a Business Indicators

Country Procedures (number) Time (days) Cost (percent of income per capita) Angola 8 68 151.1 Botswana 10 61 2.1 Lesotho 7 40 27.0 Namibia 10 66 20.4 South Africa 6 22 5.9 Swaziland 13 61 33.9

Figure III-4.

Zimbabwe: Civil Service Salaries

Comparative Infrastructure Indicators, 2008

Indicators Zimbabwe Angola Botswana Lesotho Namibia South Africa Swaziland Sub-

Saharan

Africa

Average Low

income

Countries Lower

middle

income

Countries Upper

middle

income

Countries
Access to electricity (% of population) 40 12 22 5 34 66 27 26 67 84 Electric power consumption (kwh per capita) 831 109 3860 719 642 929 2566 Improved water source (% of population with access 81 53 95 79 87 88 62 65 63 83 92 Improved sanitation facilities (% of population with access) 53 31 42 37 25 65 48 37 38 68 84 Total telephone subscribers per 100 inhabitants 8 11 54 17 31 82 23 19 9 37 85
  • Measurinģ and Assessing Zimbabwe’s Net External Position

In this section, we estimate the NFA position based on the sum of two components: a backward-looking component —Zimbabwe’s NFA (financial) position—and forward-looking component based on the NPV of Zimbabwe’s mining receipts. Subsequently, we provide a qualitative assessment of the implications of the NFA position, including estimates of the NPV of mining receipts, for assessing Zimbabwe’s potential to outgrow the existing debt overhang.

Estimates of Zimbabwe’s NFA (Financial)

In light of significant data limitations, we will rely on two different methodologies to estimate Zimbabwe’s NFA at the end of 2009. Both methodologies produce estimates of the back-ward-looking measure of the NFA of a similar magnitude.

The first methodology is based on the updated External Wealth database constructed by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007) , containing information on the value of external assets and liabilities for 145 countries between 1970 and 2008. The stock measures are based on cumulative flow data with valuation adjustments complemented by stock data wherever available. We extend the series for Zimbabwe by adding the current account deficit for 2009 to the NFA stock for 2008 provided in the updated External Wealth database. 21 As shown in Table III—5 , Zimbabwe’s external position stood at -US$8.2 billion (-186 percent of GDP) by the end of 2009. Staff projections for the balance of payments imply that the country’s NFA will be -176 percent of GDP by 2015 on current policies.

Zimbabwe, External Position, 2007-09

(in billions of U.S. dollars; unless otherwise indicated)

Estimated 2007 2008 2009 External Wealth -5.8 -6.3 -8.2 Public and private net assets -7.2 -8.1 of which: Public and publicly guaranteed debt -5.5 -6.4 (in percent of GDP) External Wealth -160 -186 Public and private net assets -182 -184 of which: Public and publicly guaranteed debt -139 -146

The second methodology to derive Zimbabwe’s NFA is based on existing public debt data complemented with estimates of private net assets. We obtain estimates of private assets and liabilities using additional information from the Joint BIS-IMF-OECD-World Bank Statistics on External Debt Database, which contains estimates of cross-border deposits of and loans to banking and non-banking institutions in Zimbabwe with/from banks reporting to the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) at the end of the second quarter of 2009. With external public and publicly guaranteed debt at US$6.4 billion and gross international reserves at US$0.3 billion at the end of 2009, we estimate that Zimbabwe’s NFA stood at about -US$8.1 billion dollars (-184 percent of GDP). Table III-5 summarizes the results.

Measurinģ Mineral Wealth

The backward-looking estimates may, however, understate the true external wealth position of Zimbabwe, which is arguably rich in mineral resources. When GDP is measured in 2009 prices, mining represented more than 13 percent of value added and mining exports accounted for 38 percent of goods exports in 2009 ( Figure III—5 ). In addition, in recent years, more than 30 percent of manufacturing exports were the by-product of mining production (for example, ferro-alloys).

Figure III-5.

Zimbabwe: Exports and Value Added by Industry, 1990-2014

Incorporating measures of mining wealth in estimates of the NFA presents many challenges, mainly related to lack of reliable data on proven reserves and uncertainties related to potential extraction rates and world commodity prices. We estimate the NPV of gold and platinum receipts—the highest value commodities in Zimbabwe. We also estimate the NPV of gem-quality diamond related receipts but treat them separately, given the uncertainties currently surrounding potential future revenues. Our estimates are based on the following assumption: 22

Proven reserves . Given the uncertainty surrounding proven reserves, we discount flows only for the next 20 years. Based on existing estimates, gold and platinum mineral deposits will not be exhausted by that time based on assumed extraction rates (see below). Because of discounting, at least 95 percent of the NPV is attained within about the first 20 years of extraction at the assumed discount rates, as shown in Figure III—6 . 23 Therefore, truncating the cashflow after 20 years may not understate significantly the present value.

Figure III-6.

Zimbabwe: NPV of Gold Cash Flows

Gold and platinum

Extraction rates . We consider two production streams: (i) the current staff projection for mining output and (ii) the Zimbabwe Chamber of Mines optimistic scenario for the next five years, which would require timely resolution of issues with the regulatory environment, property rights, and infrastructure bottlenecks. The staff scenario assumes production will reach 5.9 metric tons of gold and 7.1 metric tons of platinum by 2015. The Zimbabwe Chamber of Mines scenario assumes Zimbabwe can produce 35 metric tons of gold and 13 metric tons of platinum by 2015. We further assume that in both scenarios the level of production remains constant after 2015 ( Figure III—7 ).

Discount factor . Income streams are discounted at 15, 17, and 20 percent, mainly reflecting various assumptions about risk premia. 24

Prices . Although, gold and platinum world prices are at their historic highs ( Figure III—8 ), our calculations assume they remain constant at their current nominal levels: US$1,002 per troy ounce of gold and US$1,269 per troy ounce of platinum.

Extraction costs . We use an estimate of extraction costs from the Zimbabwe Chamber of Mines of US$502 per troy ounce. This assumes economies of scale would be realized and per once costs would decline after significant increases in production. At current low production levels, the costs of production in both gold and platinum are significantly higher: US$800 per troy ounce for gold and US$1,000 per troy ounce for platinum.

Figure III-7.

Zimbabwe: Gold and Platinum Production, 1990 -2014

Figure III-8.

Zimbabwe: World Gold and Platinum Prices, 1990-2014

Diamond mining does not currently generate substantial recorded export cash flows. According to Kimberley Process Rough Diamonds Statistics, Zimbabwe produced 797 thousand carats of gem-quality rough diamonds in 2008, with proceeds of US$44 million dollars. We only include the value of diamonds in our optimistic scenario because large increases in diamond production would depend on Kimberley process certification and substantial improvements in the business climate. We make the following assumptions:

Extraction rates . Zimbabwe authorities estimate production of gem-quality rough uncut diamonds could be as high as 1.1 million carats in 2010 with the potential to reach 2.4 million carats per year in the medium term. We assume 1.1 million carats are extracted in 2010—a substantial increase from the 2008 levels—and production reaches 2.4 million carats by 2012.

Prices . Rough diamond prices depend on a number of factors, including color and size. According to Kimberley Process Rough Diamonds Statistics, Zimbabwe received an average price of US$55 per carat in 2008. The world average price per carat was US$78, but some producers were able to obtain higher prices. The Zimbabwe Chamber of Mines estimates that Zimbabwe diamonds could fetch as much as US$100— US$120 per carat. In the optimistic scenario, we assume Zimbabwe could sell its diamonds for US$100 per carat.

Extraction costs . Diamond extraction costs vary widely depending on the type of mining. The Zimbabwe Chamber of Mines estimates that for a rich alluvial deposit, the cost per carat varies between US$3 and US$10 per carat while for a kimberlitic deposit the costs could be as high as US$50 to US$70 per carat. Because a large share of Zimbabwe’s diamond deposits is of the alluvial type, we assume extraction costs of US$10 per carat under the optimistic scenario.

Under a 17-percent discount rate, we estimate the gross present value (GPV) of mineral resource export receipts, including diamond proceeds, at US$9.2 billion under an optimistic scenario and US$3.0 billion under the more conservative staff scenario ( Table III—6 ). Taking into account extraction costs, the net present value (NPV) is estimated at US$5.4 billion under the optimistic scenario and US$1.7 billion under the staff scenario, respectively. (NPV estimates at 15 and 20 percent discount rates are presented in Table III—7 .) 25

Zimbabwe: Present Value of Mining Wealth, 2009

(In millions of U.S. dollars; unless otherwise indicated)

2009 Optimistic Gross present value of mining wealth 9,154 Gross present value of gold 4,854 Gross present value of platinum 3,067 Gross present value of diamonds 1,233 Net present value of mining wealth 5,400 Net present value of gold 2,432 Net present value of platinum 1,858 Net present value of diamonds 1,110 Staff projection Gross present value of mining wealth 3,037 Gross present value of gold 1,148 Gross present value of platinum 1,889 Net present value of mining wealth 1,720 Net present value of gold 575 Net present value of platinum 1,145 Discount rate for NPV of mining wealth 17%

Zimbabwe: Net Foreign Assets, 2009

Discount rate 15% 17% 20% Optimistic (bllions of U.S. dollars) Gross present value of gold 5.6 4.9 4.0 Gross present value of platinum 3.5 3.1 2.6 Gross present value of diamonds 1.4 1.2 1.2 Net present value of gold 2.8 2.4 2.0 Net present value of platinum 2.1 1.9 1.6 Net present value of diamonds 1.3 1.1 0.9 External wealth -2.0 -2.8 -3.6 Public and private debt -1.9 -2.7 -3.6 (percent of GDP) External wealth -45.6 -63.3 -82.9 Non-mineral primary current account norm 0.4 0.6 0.8 Gap (Norm- Actual) 35.8 35.9 36.1 Public and private debt -43.6 -61.3 -80.9 Non-mineral primary current account norm 0.4 0.6 0.8 Gap (Norm- Actual) 35.8 35.9 36.1 (billions of U.S. dollars) Net present value of gold 0.6 0.6 0.5 Net present value of platinum 1.3 1.1 1.0 External wealth -6.3 -6.5 -6.7 Public and private debt -6.2 -6.4 -6.6 (percent of GDP) External wealth -142.4 -147.0 -152.1 Non-mineral primary current account norm 1.3 1.4 1.4 Gap (Norm- Actual) 36.7 36.7 36.8 Public and private debt -140.4 -145.0 -150.1 Non-mineral primary current account norm 1.3 1.4 1.4 Gap (Norm- Actual) 36.7 36.7 36.7 : Years to attain 95 percent of NPV (n) 21 19 16 Long-run interest rate (percent) 8.0 8.0 8.0 Long-run real GDP growth (percent) 7.0 7.0 7.0 Actual non-mining primary current account -35.3 -35.3 -35.3
2009

External Sustainability Assessment

Under the most optimistic assumptions (the optimistic extraction scenario including diamonds), a 17 percent discount rate, and the lowest measure of the financial NFA, Zimbabwe’s NFA, including mining wealth, is about -63 percent of GDP ( Table III—7 ). Just maintaining this level of the negative NFA (which is by no means an equilibrium value) would require generating positive non-mineral primary external current account surpluses of about 0.6 percent of GDP. 26 Because the 2009 non-mineral primary external current account deficit is more than 35 percent of GDP in 2009, 27 the gap between the “norm” and the actual balance is close to 36 percent of GDP. Such an adjustment in the non-mineral primary current account balance is not feasible in the foreseeable future, even if the challenges with competitiveness and business climate are addressed without further delays. This finding is robust to assuming a discount rate of 15 percent. Therefore, sound policies supported by debt relief are the only feasible option for Zimbabwe to reestablish external stability.

  • Brinģinģ Budģet Mineral Revenues Forward: How Much Can be Mobilized?

Authorities are actively debating an option of bringing forward mining revenues to repay external arrears on public and publicly guaranteed debt and obtain access to new financing. The analysis of external sustainability demonstrated that the economy as a whole would not be able to generate sufficient foreign exchange inflows to attain a sustainable external position without sound policies and debt relief. The analysis of the present value of the government’s in-take of mineral export receipts reinforces this finding.

Under the most optimistic scenario and assuming a 17 percent discount rate, the present value of budget mining revenues is US$1.9 billion (42 percent of GDP) in 2009 ( Table III-8 ). Because outstanding government obligations are approximately US$6.4 billion (146 percent of GDP) in 2009, government net wealth (excluding future non-mining revenues which are non-exhaustible) is about -US$4.6 billion (-104 percent of GDP). Government mining wealth would not make a major dent in Zimbabwe’s gross public debt or provide sufficient resources to settle external arrears (US$4.6 billion, 104 percent of GDP) even if the government were able to mortgage its future fiscal revenues from mining, for example, by borrowing internationally an amount equivalent to the present value of mining budget revenues. More importantly, the government would not be able to generate significant primary non-mineral surpluses to ensure its intertemporal solvency in the foreseeable future.

Zimbabwe: Fiscal Wealth, 2009-10

2009 2010 (millions of U.S. dollars) NPV of fiscal wealth from mining 1,860 2,030 Public external debt 6,417 6,765 of which: Arrears 4,490 4,948 Government net position -4,556 -4,736 (percent of GDP) NPV of fiscal wealth from mining 42 39 Public external debt 146 132 of which: Arrears 102 96 Government net position -104 -92 Overall balance -2.8 -7.6 Cash balance 1.2 -4.5 Primary balance 0.6 -4.4 Interest payments 3.4 3.1 of which paid 0.5 0.1 Non-mining Primary balance to stabilize 1.0 0.9 debt : Long-run interest rate (percent) 8.0 Long-run real GDP growth (percent) 7.0 Discount rate (percent) 17.0 Profit tax (percent) 31.0 Royalty (percent of production value) 3.0

Going forward, a strategy focusing on sound policies and debt relief would help achieve external and growth sustainability in at least three ways. First, sound policies would support macroeconomic stability and economic growth and also help Zimbabwe establish the track record needed for debt relief from official creditors. Second, debt relief, in turn, would immediately increase Zimbabwe’s net wealth by reducing its debt obligations and increasing the value of mining wealth through a reduction in country risk. Third, the government would have access to fresh financing, at lower costs, which would create room for much-needed public investment, facilitating growth in both mining and non-mining sectors.

  • Appendix III-1. Appendix Optimal Portfolio Choice and the Risk Premium

Consider the following simplified version of a capital asset pricing model in which a representative consumer/investor is optimally allocating his savings between a safe and a risky asset with returns r f and r r t . Then one can show that the Euler equations for the safe and risky assets imply

where m t + 1 = ( 1 1 + ρ ) E t u ′ ( c t + 1 ) u ′ ( c t ) i.e. risky assets have an expected return equal to the risk-free rate plus a risk premium. The higher the covariance of an asset’s return with the marginal utility of consumption, the lower is the expected return on the asset. Thus, if we have an estimate of the risk premium, the interest rate we use to discount the net present value of assets will fully capture the riskiness of an asset and investor’s risk aversion (embodied in the marginal utility of consumption). We can rewrite this in the familiar regression format:

where β = cov ( ( 1 + r r + 1 r ) , m t + 1 ) ⁡ var ⁡ ( m t + 1 ) is the regression coefficient of the asset return on the m t+1 . In the more standard (non-consumption) capital asset pricing model (CAPM), the asset’s riskiness is assessed against market return rather than consumption returns.

How can we assess the risk premium for Zimbabwe? In all likelihood, given its recent history of hyperinflation, political unrest, and debt default, Zimbabwe has a high level of country risk. Its December 2009 International Country Risk Guide financial risk rating was the lowest in Africa. Damodaran (2009) provides estimates of country equity risk based on Moody’s country rating ( http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/ ). Zimbabwe is not included in the database, but Damodoran estimates that countries with the lowest Moody’s ratings have a risk premium of 15 percent over the premium for a mature equity market. This premium should be added to an estimate of the risk premium for an investment in a mature equity market. We consider two possibilities:

Damodaran (2009) estimates that the historical risk premium over Treasury bonds for the U.S. equity market is 4.5 percent. This would imply an overall risk premium of 19.5 percent for Zimbabwe, if we add the extra 15 percent applied for countries with the lowest Moody’s ratings. To obtain an estimate of the discount rate, we should add this premium to a U.S. government bond rate. Since the U.S. 30-year Treasury bond rate was a little more than 4.5 percent at the end of 2009, the resulting discount rate for Zimbabwe would be around 24 percent.

An alternative is to use the standard discount rate for mining projects which accounts for standard risks in mining (12-15 percent; see Topal [2008]) and add the country risk premium. This would imply a discount rate between 27 and 30 percent.

Overall, this analysis suggests that the appropriate discount rate should be between 24 and 30 percent. Given the uncertainty surrounding the appropriate discount rate, we use rates between 15 and 20 percent. As a result, our estimates of the NPV of mining cash flows may constitute an upper bound on Zimbabwe’s mining wealth.

Chapter 4. Creatinģ Fiscal Space for Growth and Development in Zimbabwe 28

Between 2000 and 2008, spiraling inflation, brought on by quasi-fiscal activities of the Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe, and a 40 percent contraction of output, undermined revenue collection and public service delivery . Largely due to the anzi effect (1969), budget revenue fell from more than 28 percent of GDP in 1998 to less than 5 percent a decade later. The result was an almost total collapse in public services. By the end of 2008, most schools and many hospitals had closed, transport and electricity networks were severely compromised, and a water-borne cholera epidemic had claimed more than 4,000 lives.

Following implementation of the government’s short-term economic recovery program in 2009, revenues have recovered , although they have not yet reached the levels recorded prior to the decade of the economic decline ( Figure IV—1 ). This recovery in revenues was largely attributable to price stability, a well established revenue administration infrastructure that had existed prior to hyperinflation; along with revenue measures introduced in 2009 (see Appendix Table IV—1.1 ).

Figure IV-1.

Zimbabwe: Total Revenues, 1998-2009

(in percent of GDP)

Like many fragile states in Africa, post-hyperinflation Zimbabwe faces the three challenges of rebuilding its public finances, promoting economic growth, and reducing poverty . Going forward, the authorities need to ensure that a sufficient proportion of the resurgent revenues are devoted to supporting growth and improving living standards for all Zimbabweans.

  • Fiscal Space for Growth-Enhancing Expenditure: Cross-Country Perspective

A large body of theoretical and empirical literature suggests that infrastructure and human capital investment play a central role in fostering and sustaining economic growth . Endogenous growth models developed by Barro (1991) , King and Rebelo (1995) , and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2003) emphasize the externalities between expenditures on education, healthcare and core network infrastructures, and increased factor productivity.

Zimbabwe devotes a much lower share of its resources to these growth-enabling interventions, especially capital expenditure, than other countries in the region ( Figure IV-2 ) . In 2009, domestically-financed public sector investment was just 1.0 percent of GDP in Zimbabwe. This is significantly lower than the levels seen elsewhere in Africa. Moreover, more than 60 percent of budgeted capital expenditure in Zimbabwe in 2009 was directed towards the acquisition of buildings, office furniture, cars, and related items.

Figure IV-2.

Zimbabwe: Composition of Government Expenditure, 2009

(percent of GDP)

Figure IV-3.

Zimbabwe: Composition of Expenditure, Budget versus Out-Turn, 2009

Figure IV-4.

Zimbabwe: Nominal and Effective Tax Rates, 2009

In many key social sectors in Zimbabwe, donors finance some capital expenditures directly as part of humanitarian assistance . In 2009, donors financed US$156 million (3 percent of GDP) in off-budget capital expenditures, mainly directed towards the health and education sectors. This is somewhat below regional averages.

The legacy of underinvestment in Zimbabwe is acting as a major constraint on the country’s growth potential . In the World Economic Forum’s most recent Global Competitiveness Report, inadequate supply of infrastructure was the third most frequently cited problem with doing business in Zimbabwe after access to finance and political instability. Of 133 countries surveyed, Zimbabwe’s economic infrastructure was ranked 101 st with the quality of electricity supply ranking among the five worst in the sample.

In 2009, government expenditure on human capital-enhancing services (health and education) as a share of Zimbabwe’s GDP is in line with regional comparators ( Table IV-1 ) . However, virtually all budgeted expenditures on health and education are allocated to wages in Zimbabwe. In 2009, the central government budget allocated only US$11 million (1.1 percent of total expenditures) to recurrent non-wage expenditures in health and education. In contrast, donors’ contribution to health and education current expenditure is substantial (off-budget current grants of about US$236 million or 5 percent of GDP). This relatively sizeable amount reflects the large extent of humanitarian challenges facing Zimbabwe.

Selected African Countries: Public Sector Healthcare and Education Expenditure, 2009 1/

1/ IMF staff estimates; definitions of health and education spending vary between countries.

2/ Excluding off-budget donor financing

Percent of GDP U.S. dollars

per capita Percent of GDP U.S. dollars

per capita
Angola 0.9 34 1.2 46 Cameroon 0.7 8 2.6 29 Cape Verde 3.3 112 8.9 306 Ethiopia 0.7 3 1.4 5 Ghana 1.4 9 4.5 30 Guinea-Bissau 0.8 4 3.0 15 Cote d’lvoire 0.9 9 4.8 50 Kenya 1.7 15 6.1 56 Madagascar 3.6 15 7.1 29 Mali 2.0 13 5.1 33 Mauritius 2.7 183 4.9 333 Mozambique 2.6 12 5.0 23 Niger 2.5 9 4.8 18 Nigeria 3.3 38 3.7 42 Rwanda 1.3 7 3.9 21 Seychelles 2.3 203 3.4 306 Senegal 2.1 21 5.9 59 Sierra Leone 0.8 3 3.7 12 Namibia 2.7 124 5.9 268 Tanzania 0.3 2 0.7 4 Togo 3.8 16 4.9 21 Uganda 0.8 4 2.2 10 Zambia 2.5 27 3.2 35 Zimbabwe 1.2 4 5.8 22 Average 1.9 36 4.3 74 Standard Deviation 1.0 58 1.9 106
Health Education

Zimbabwe is ranked near the top third of countries for the quality of its education system . This is attributable largely to the importance granted by the government to education since independence. However, this achievement is now under threat. After many years of declining GDP, the absolute volume of resources devoted to education is much less than it was a decade ago. The large declines in capital investment and nonwage current expenses in education pose serious concerns that the quality of education could quickly decline even further, placing a more binding constraint on growth in the longer term.

To address this legacy of underinvestment, including in social sectors, Zimbabwe would need to bring public sector capital expenditure above the levels found in more development-oriented states in Africa . Increasing domestically-financed capital expenditure from 1.5 percent to 5.5 percent of GDP would align infrastructure investment with that in Kenya and make it slightly above Uganda, Mozambique and Tanzania. This would require Zimbabwe to identify additional fiscal space of 4—5 percent of GDP . The next section of this paper considers a number of options for creating fiscal space of this magnitude.

  • Options for Creatinģ Fiscal Space in Zimbabwe

Broadly speaking, the Zimbabwean government has three options for generating fiscal space of this magnitude over the next few years :

Mobilizing additional revenues through strengthening revenue administration and eliminating tax expenditures.

Restraining the cost of the country’s relatively expensive public administration; in particular wages.

Resolving external payments arrears with the support of the international community and gaining access to fresh IFI financing and additional donor support.

Improvinģ revenue performance

Revenue performance could be increased further through strengthening tax administration and eliminating tax exemptions . A decade of high inflation and economic decline weakened many of the key tax administration functions of the Zimbabwean Revenue Agency (ZIMRA) and delayed its modernization. The taxpayer register became outdated, while core audit and investigation activities were made redundant because of rapidly declining real values of corporate balance sheets and incomes under hyperinflation. Persistent economic difficulties and significant restrictions on prices and goods markets that existed prior to 2009 led to widespread informal activity, making it more difficult to collect taxes. Despite recent improvements to tax legislation in line with Fund Technical Assistance (see Appendix Table IV—1.1 ), the tax regime remains outdated and multiple rates and exemptions make it excessively complex.

The structure and level of customs duties is particularly problematic . Despite recent rate reductions, there are still 17 customs duty bands, ranging from zero to 100 percent. Nevertheless, only 4.3 percent of customs revenues are generated from lines with tariffs of greater than 40 percent. The current structure discourages trade, places impediments upon growth, and creates opportunities for corruption.

Zimbabwe’s tax regime is also characterized by significant and widespread tax distortions . These take the form of concessional rates, exemptions, allowances, reliefs, and deductions and rebates for particular activities, goods, or classes of taxpayer. Zimbabwe’s Income Tax Act alone itemizes almost 100 different exemptions from the standard definitions set out in the act. There is also a long list of goods that are zero-rated or exempt from the VAT, including most agricultural items, basic foodstuffs, and household commodities. That said, Zimbabwe’s VAT, corporate income and PAYE tax rates are broadly in line with the rates prevailing in the region.

There is a large divergence between nominal tax rates and effective rates on all the main taxes . The existing nominal rates, in part, compensate for widespread use of exemptions and weaknesses in tax administration, with the tax burden falling heavily on a comparatively small number of well-established tax payers.

A comprehensive reform package of administrative improvements, streamlined tax exemptions, and a lower number of customs duties tariff bands could yield an additional 1.1 to 1.9 percent of GDP in revenues per year ( Table IV-3 ) . The objective of the reform effort is to raise effective rates on the main revenue-raising taxes, such as the VAT, PAYE, and corporate income tax by 0.5 to 1 percent. Regarding tax administration, the creation of a large tax payers unit, IT infrastructure upgrades at ZIMRA, and ongoing preparations to strengthen post clearance audit and investigations at customs should have priority. While these reforms would generate additional revenues, there would also be a potential growth dividend from simplifying the tax structure and reducing nominal tax rates. The recommended reforms would reduce distortions, improve the business environment, and contribute to higher economic growth.

Zimbabwe: Customs Duties, 2009 (nominal tariff rates)

1/ Revenues collected on customs lines that were non-zero rated before September 2009.

Tariff Rate Number of lines February 2009 Number of lines September 2009 Percent of customs duties collected, February- December 2009 Proposed tariff structure 0.00 471 602 3.4 0 0.05 2,221 2,107 22.0 2,709 0.10 597 1,014 12.6 0 0.15 923 549 14.8 0 0.20 362 321 10.7 1,980 0.25 101 95 5.8 0 0.30 1 1 0.0 0 0.40 1,116 1,102 26.3 1,192 0.45 1 1 0.0 0 0.60 31 31 2.0 0 0.65 8 8 0.2 0 0.70 1 1 0.4 0 0.75 6 6 0.2 0 0.80 16 16 0.5 0 0.85 5 5 0.2 0 0.95 12 12 0.1 0 1.00 9 10 0.6 0 Percentage of revenues collected on lines with tariff duties greater than 40 percent 4.3 4.3

Zimbabwe: Measures to Increase Fiscal Space

Estimated effective tax rate Anticipated increase in effective rate Revenue yield Reform tariff structure 7.4 1.1 0.7 i) Eliminate zero band; ii) set minimum band of 5 percent; iii) harmonize bands between 10 percent and 35 percent at 20 percent; iv) set a maximum tariff of 40 percent. Corporate income tax 7.3 1.0 0.2 Increase effective rate by one percent by reducing incentives, clarifying rules for claiming deductions of capital allowances, repealing the exemptions for interest income, and taxing all forms of income from capital. Income tax 6.5 1.0 0.6 Increase effective rate by one percent by i) introducing new income tax law based on Fund technical advice; ii) maintaining the income threshold for PIT at its present nominal level; adopting a worldwide taxation of resident individuals. Domestic VAT collection 4.1 0.5 0.5 Increase effective rate on domestically charged VAT by 0.5 percent by reducing the number of zero-rated goods; changing the VAT status of the remaining goods from zero rated to exempt (except for export goods, which should remain zero rated). VAT collected on imports 5.6 0.5 0.3 Increase the effective rate on VAT collected on imports by i) establishing a national post clearance audit office; developing a national anti-smuggling strategy; bringing fuel products into the VAT net. Limiting central government wage growth 2.6-4.1 i) 10 percent headcount reduction in 2010-11; ii) wage restraint in 2011-14; iii) raise the wage compression ratio from 2.6 in 2010 to 3 by 2015.

Restraininģ the Cost of the Public Service

Based on any standard measure of affordability, Zimbabwe currently has one of the most expensive civil service wage bills in Africa . Zimbabwe historically had one of the more expensive public administrations in Africa. This is, in part, due to high public sector wages within the region, which has created unrealistic expectations. However, the real value of civil service pay was rapidly eroded during hyperinflation that reached its apogee in the latter half of 2008, when the average civil servant salary fell to an equivalent of a few U.S. dollars per month. Nevertheless, public sector pay decisions made since dollarization have returned the civil service wage bill to regional highs:

As a percent of GDP, the 2010 budget provided for a central government wage bill (including benefits) amounting to 14.2 percent one of the highest in Sub-Saharan Africa and well above the 7.1 percent average for the region.

Based on the most recent budget plans, the 2010 central government wage bill will consume about 55 percent of government revenues, the highest in Sub-Saharan Africa; well above the 26 percent regional average.

In U.S. dollar terms, the typical Zimbabwean teacher earns US$161 per month. 29 This is well above wage rates paid in neighboring countries with similar levels of per capita income (Malawi, Uganda, and Zambia).

The authorities’ medium-term projections are even more alarming . The medium-term budget framework sees the wage bill increasing to 15.9 percent of GDP and 59.5 of revenues in 2011 ( Table IV-—4 ), and further to 20.8 of GDP and 77.8 of revenues 30 in 2012. This rate of growth is unsustainable and will inevitably crowd out other government expenditures, including public sector investment.

Zimbabwe: Wage Bill Projections 1/

1/ Wages and benefits include monthly gross salaries, transport and housing allowances, and “13th month” bonus.

2/ Relative to the authorities’ 2010 scenario.

2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Wages and benefits (in percent of GDP) 10.0 14.2 15.9 Wages and benefits (in percent of revenues) 44.9 54.2 59.5 Wages and benefits (in percent of GDP) 10.0 13.1 12.2 11.6 11.1 Wages and benefits (in percent of revenues) 44.9 48.9 44.1 40.8 38.4 In percent of GDP 1.2 2.0 2.6 3.2 In percent of revenues 5.3 10.1 13.4 15.8

A significant reduction in the civil service head count would be a key component of a wage bill reduction strategy . Ghost workers are a widely acknowledged problem in the civil service and grant aided institutions. The authorities are conducting a payroll audit, which could lead to a potential headcount reduction of about 10 percent. Furthermore, termination of temporary contracts and attrition also would reduce headcount. Finally, keeping wage growth rates below nominal GDP growth would gradually reduce wage costs as a percent of GDP. However, a failure to address the rising proportion of public sector wages increases the possibility that wage arrears could occur in the event of negative shocks to revenues.

Potential for Donor Support

Zimbabwe could enjoy significant additional budgetary resources once policies have been strengthened and external payments arrears have been resolved with the support of the international community . This would create “upside” potential, generating further fiscal space for growth-enhancing capital expenditure.

The magnitude and timing of donor financing of capital expenditures is uncertain . However, the experiences of other African countries offer some guidance. As shown in Table IV—5 , the magnitude of flows varies, but Zimbabwe could potentially receive flows in the range of 1.5 to 4 percent of GDP in addition to the current off-budget grants of US$156 million (3 percent of GDP). These amounts could be even larger considering the state of disrepair of Zimbabwe’s infrastructure after a decade of economic decline.

Selected African Countries, Donor Financed Capital Expenditure, 2009

Ghana 5.2 Kenya 2.1 Malawi 1.4 Mozambique 7.2 Tanzania 4.9 Uganda 1.4

Together, the revenue and wage restraint measures described above could generate about 5 percent of GDP of fiscal space . This would enable Zimbabwe to match levels of domestically-financed infrastructure investment seen in neighboring countries. More than half of these measures could come from restraining civil services salaries. Zimbabwe could also further increase the magnitude of fiscal space by resolving its external payments arrears with the support of the international community.

  • Appendix IV-1. Zimbabwe: Recent Tax Policy and Administration Measures

Zimbabwe: Recent Tax Policy and Administration Measures

Implementation Measure date Introduce a 1 percent withholding tax. June 2009 Harmonize the excise duty on beer, wine, and spirits at 40 percent. Apply identical rates to both June 2009 and domestic production and imports. 2010 budget Limit on the deduction of interest for Corporate Income Tax purposes (thin capitalization rule). 2009 Establish a dedicated risk management unit at each regional customs center. 2009 Remove the discretionary power of exemption from royalties. 2009 Reimpose royalty on gold. 2009 Align the import duties at 40 percent for all types of wine and lager beer. June 2009 Reduce tariff rates on capital goods, telephones, and computers. June 2009 Increase the excise duty on cigarettes, and assess it as a specific duty. September 2009 Repeal the mid-month VAT advance payment requirement. September 2010 Improve return and document receipt processes to minimize the need to keep stamped 2009 duplicates. Issue tax clearance certificates to compliant only taxpayers. 2009 Change the method for assessing VAT on imports to duty-inclusive basis. 2010 budget Establish Large taxpayers unit. April 1, 2010 Reduce the top rate of tax to 35 percent for all income above US$1,000 per month. 2010 budget Tax rate on business income reduced to 25 percent. 2010 budget Levy income tax on mining companies at the proposed new general corporate rate of 25 percent. 2010 budget Introduce a turnover-based tax for traders and service providers below the VAT threshold. 2010 budget

Same Series

  • Central African Economic and Monetary Community: A New Medium-Term Approach for International Reserve Management
  • Opening Up in the Caucasus and Central Asia: Policy Frameworks to Support Regional and Global Integration
  • Macroeconomic Research in Low-income Countries
  • The Development Path Less Traveled: The Experience of Rwanda
  • Building Resilient Banking Sectors in the Caucasus and Central Asia
  • Policy Advice to Asia in the COVID-19 Era
  • A Growth-Friendly Path for Building Fiscal Buffers in the Caucuses and Central Asia
  • Opportunity for All: Promoting Growth and Inclusiveness in the Middle East and North Africa
  • Growing Pains: Is Latin American Prepared for Population Aging?
  • Monetary Finance: Do Not Touch, or Handle with Care?

Other Publishers

Asian development bank.

  • Asia Bond Monitor - September 2023
  • The Influence of US Dollar Funding Conditions on Asian Financial Markets
  • A Comparative Analysis of Tax Administration in Asia and the Pacific: Sixth Edition
  • Strengthening India's Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers: Learnings from the Asian Experience

Inter-American Development Bank

  • Financial Dollarization and Dedollarization
  • Real Exchange Rates, Dollarization and Industrial Employment in Latin America
  • Living with Dollarization and the Route to Dedollarization
  • Dedollarization, Indexation and Nominalization: The Chilean Experience
  • Manna from Heaven: The Impact of Nonrenewable Resource Revenues on Other Revenues of Resource Exporters in Latin America and the Caribbean
  • Analysis of Research Department's Activities and the Work of the Bank: Economic Assessment Reports (EARs)/High Level Consultation Meetings (Encerronas)
  • Preventing Sudden Stops in Net Capital Flows
  • Toward the Greening of the Gold Mining Sector of Guyana: Transition Issues and Challenges
  • Factsheet Resilience Solutions for the Road Sector in South Africa
  • Taxation and Economic Growth in Colombia

The World Bank

  • Inflation Threshold Levels and Economic Growth in the Franc Zone Countries
  • Kingdom of Lesotho: Country Partnership Framework 2016-2020.
  • Digging Beneath the Surface: An Exploration of the Net Benefits of Mining in Southern Africa
  • Dollarization and Exchange Rate Fluctuations
  • Deposit dollarization and the financial sector in emerging economies
  • The Distributional Impact of Fiscal Policy in South Africa
  • The impact of export tax incentives on export performance: Evidence from the automotive sector in South Africa
  • Shock Persistence and the Choice of Foreign Exchange Regime: An Empirical Note from Mexico
  • Pricing currency risk: facts and puzzles from currency boards
  • Exchange Rate Volatility and FDI Inflows: Evidence from Cross-Country Panel Data
  • Share on facebook Share on linkedin Share on twitter

Cover Departmental Papers

Table of Contents

  • Appendix II-2. CMA Institutional Framework17
  • View raw image
  • Download Powerpoint Slide

zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

International Monetary Fund Copyright © 2010-2021. All Rights Reserved.

zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

  • [195.190.12.77]
  • 195.190.12.77

Character limit 500 /500

This site uses cookies to optimize functionality and give you the best possible experience. If you continue to navigate this website beyond this page, cookies will be placed on your browser. To learn more about cookies, click here .

Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.

To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to  upgrade your browser .

Enter the email address you signed up with and we'll email you a reset link.

  • We're Hiring!
  • Help Center

paper cover thumbnail

Inflation Impact of an Exchange Rate Adjustment: The Case of Zimbabwe 1990 -2006

Profile image of mike nyamazana sikwila

Related Papers

African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development

Nyasha Mahonye

zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

International Research Journal of Finance and Economics

Carren Pindiriri

The study examines and assesses the causes of inflation in the post-dollarized Zimbabwe. It employs time series econometric methodology based on monthly data to examine the probable factors influencing inflation in the post-dollarized Zimbabwe. The influence on inflation of factors such imports, consumer expectation about future inflation, exchange rate, interest rates, output growth and money supply, among others is investigated. Although interest rate has been found to be one of the major determinants of inflation in Zimbabwe by studies done during the pre-dollarization period, this study finds statistical evidence of an insignificant relationship between interest rate and inflation in dollarized Zimbabwe. The study however finds evidence that consumer expectations about future inflation, money supply, current exchange rate, and import value are the major factors influencing post-dollarization inflation.

Journal of Economics and …

Wellington Madesha

william kavila

This paper empirically investigates the reaction of inflation to macro-economic shocks using the Vector Error Correction modelling approach (VECM) with monthly data from 2009:01 to 2012:12. The Zimbabwean economy was dollarised during this period, after having abandoned its own currency in 2009, following the hyperinflation episode of 2007-2008. The empirical findings show that the reaction of price formation in Zimbabwe to external shocks, such as the appreciation or depreciation of the South African rand against the US dollar and the increase in international food and oil prices is immediate with permanent effects. Specifically, the study found that an appreciation of the South African rand against the US dollar, results in a sharp increase in inflation during the first 6 months and the effects are permanent. Similarly, a positive shock to international oil prices also results in a sharp increase in inflation, during the first 6 months, remaining high over the forest period. The i...

wellington garikai bonga

Tafirenyika Sunde

In order to estimate the inflation function in Zimbabwe we used cointegration and error-correction mechanism (a methodology popularized by Hendry etal (1989)). This approach has received extensive empirical support. Right now the approach seems to have generally settled the long-standing problem over the instability of the inflation model (function). Using the above technique, we managed to come up with a stable inflation model for Zimbabwe. This study also established that one must go beyond a simple monetary account of the inflation process even if inflation will always have a monetary dimension. Other factors that were found to be significant in explaining inflation in Zimbabwe are: real output, budget deficit, exchange rate depreciation and interest rates. The results that we got fitted very well all the theoretical priors, and they also concur with the studies done elsewhere for both the developed and the developing countries. Introduction In Zimbabwe inflation throughout the 1...

Social Science Research Network

Thandinkosi Ndhlela

Mark Ellyne

Zimbabwe’s 2008 hyperinflation is said to be the second highest in recorded history, and provides an interesting case study of policy failure. We explore possible motivating factors behind the hyperinflation to understand why it happened and persisted for so long, and who benefited from it. The paper examines the exchange rate–inflation spiral and explains how a large parallel foreign exchange market generated high profits for some, especially state-owned enterprises and those with insider connections who could arbitrage the dual exchange rate system. The paper explores the determination of the exchange rate, and tests the purchasing power parity hypothesis. It finds that PPP held for the official exchange rate but not the parallel exchange rate, providing evidence of structural change in the economy. It examines the causality among money, prices and the exchange rate using a vector error correction model to better understand the impact of monetary policy. In examining the hyperinflation, this paper uses the “Impossible Trinity Hypothesis” to explore the possibility that Zimbabwe’s policy-makers may have been trying set both the exchange rate and monetary policy. The paper also examines the “dollarization” exit strategy and post-2008 economic policies. It argues that the choice of using the US dollar as the main currency of the dollarized Zimbabwe was not optimal based on optimal currency area theory. Additionally, subsequent policies to influence domestic liquidity and control investment have created new and serious problems for the country’s economy. This case study of Zimbabwe’s hyperinflation and subsequent dollarization provides lessons for other developing economies about conducting monetary policy and the impact of full dollarization.

Tarcicious Mufundisi

The cost of Marketing in a company is so critical that, marketing become costly in International Business, especially when devaluation hits local currency. The primary purpose of this study is to find the impact of devaluation on trade balance in Zimbabwe using the Johansen-Juselius Cointegration and Vector Error Correction Model (VECM), unit root tests, and impulse response analysis. Quarterly data for the period 1990 to 2005 is used. The result shows that devaluation is effective in improving trade balance in the long run and there is a cointegrated relationship between the real effective exchange rate and trade balance in the long run. The findings initially revealed that there is a long run relationship between trade balance and exchange rate. Secondarily the real exchange rate is an important variable to the trade balance, and that devaluation will improve trade balance in the long run, thus consistent with the Marshall-Lerner condition and finally, the results indicate no J-cu...

Loading Preview

Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.

RELATED PAPERS

International Journal of Business Management and Economic Review

Vicent Moyo

papers.ssrn.com

Tara McIndoe-Calder

mwansa chibamba

African Review of Economics and Finance

ALEXANDER MAUNE

American Scientific Research Journal for Engineering, Technology, and Sciences

Johnson Addai-Asante

Simion matsvai

Albert Makochekanwa

STEVEN JERIE

DEPRECIATION OF THE ZIMBABWE DOLLAR, CURRENCY CRISIS, INFLATION, POLITICS OF MONEY, ZIMBABWEAN CRISIS, MONETARY ECONOMICS

TIRIVASHE MADONDO

DOAJ (DOAJ: Directory of Open Access Journals)

Saudi Journal of Economics and Finance

Douglason Omotor

IMF Working Papers

Sharmini Coorey , Norbert Funke

Mutemwa Ushewokunze

The Economics and Finance Letters

Babagana M . Musti

International Journal of Physical and Social Sciences

bruce iormom

The Journal of Development Studies

Nathan Emmanuel

sonia muñoz

Tapiwa Mupakati

Ruby Munhupedzi

RELATED TOPICS

  •   We're Hiring!
  •   Help Center
  • Find new research papers in:
  • Health Sciences
  • Earth Sciences
  • Cognitive Science
  • Mathematics
  • Computer Science
  • Academia ©2024

IMAGES

  1. (PDF) Inflation Impact of an Exchange Rate Adjustment: The Case of Zimbabwe

    zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

  2. Analysis OF Zimbabwe- CASE Study

    zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

  3. Hyperinflation in zimbabwe part 1

    zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

  4. (PDF) Monetary Reforms and Inflation Dynamics in Zimbabwe

    zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

  5. (PDF) Exchange rate impact on output and inflation: A historical

    zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

  6. (PDF) HYPERINFLATION IN ZIMBABWE: A BRIEF HISTORY OF THE COUNTRY, AN

    zimbabwe inflation case study pdf

COMMENTS

  1. (PDF) Lessons From Zimbabwe's Hyperinflation and Dollarization

    This case study of Zimbabwe's hyperinflation and subsequent dollarization provides lessons for other developing economies about conducting monetary policy and the

  2. Analysis of The Zimbabwean Hyperinflation Crisis: a Search for Policy

    More recent research details how countries with high inflation have stabilized their currencies, though their inflation is of lower magnitude than Zimbabwe's. Both qualitatively and quantitatively, Zimbabwe's lead-up to hyperinflation fits the mold of a modern high inflation incident, while its climax recalls the most severe WWI-era cases.

  3. PDF Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe

    It uses Zimbabwe as a case study. Through also doing a quick review of hyperinflation episodes in other countries, this book highlights that while various pre-conditions to hyper-inflation exist, the underlying mechanics of hyperinflation hold across cases.

  4. PDF Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe: Case Study and Analysis of Money Velocity

    This study's examination of money velocity found that when inflation started to accelerate in early 2000, Zimbabweans eventually abandoned the local currency altogether.

  5. PDF Zimbabwe: Challenges and Policy Options after Hyperinflation

    Introduction1 Following a decade of economic decline and hyperinflation during 2007-08, Zimbabwe's economy has started to grow. The nascent economic recovery has been supported by a significant improvement in economic policies, but important policy challenges and significant vulnerabilities remain to be addressed. A collection of three papers presents current pressing economic issues and ...

  6. PDF Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe

    Zimbabwe's Inflation Nightmare Zimbabwe's economic crisis and subsequent hyperinflation were preceded by several years of economic decline and mounting public debt. Weakening began in 1999, coinciding with periods of drought that adversely afected the agriculturally dependent nation.

  7. (PDF) Effects of hyperinflation in Zimbabwe. What next? Financial

    In summary, among the factors which have been presented under literature review to be the major causes of this hyperinflation in Zimbabwe, the study can rank them as follows (in descending order of severity): money printing (seigniorage), foreign currency shortages (with its resultant black market premium), demand pull-inflation (due to ...

  8. PDF Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe

    the household, firm and national level. It uses Zimbabwe as a case study. Through also doing a quick review of hyperinflation episodes in other countries, this book highlights that while various pre-conditions to hyper - inflation exist, the underlying mechanics of hyperinflation hold across cases.

  9. Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe: Background, Impact, and Policy

    This Palgrave Pivot investigates hyperinflation experienced in Zimbabwe in the 2000's and provides policy lessons. The authors present a full description of the Zimbabwean hyperinflation itself in relevant economic, historical and political context, and discuss parallels with other hyperinflations.

  10. (Pdf) Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe: a Brief History of The Country, an

    Zimbabwe's 2008 hyperinflation is said to be the second highest in recorded history, and provides an interesting case study of policy failure. We explore possible motivating factors behind the hyperinflation to understand why it happened and persisted for so long, and who benefited from it. The paper examines the exchange rate-inflation spiral and explains how a large parallel foreign ...

  11. PDF Determinants of Inflation in a Dollarized Economy: The Case of Zimbabwe

    Since the beginning of 2012, the country's annual inflation has been on a downward trend, initially exhibiting characteristics of disinflation and subsequently deflation. This paper seeks to shed some light on the determinants of inflation in Zimbabwe under dollarization.

  12. PDF Chapter 6

    Executive Summary This chapter results from a study of the main features of four possible monetary sys-tem options that can be potential solutions to Zimbabwe's current hyperinflationary trend. The system presented and analyzed here is dollarization, which occurs when a country makes a foreign currency (currencies) full legal tender and reduces its own currency, if any, to a subsidiary role ...

  13. Zimbabwe: A Case Study of Hyperinflation

    ITRN 503. 5/3/10. A Case Study of Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe. Introduction. Between 1980 and 1997 the government of Zimbabwe implemented monetary and fiscal. policies that allowed for the country to prosper in the global economy. Zimbabwe became an. independent state in 1980 and during its first decade as a newly formed country its inflation rate.

  14. (PDF) Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe: Money Demand, Seigniorage and Aid Shocks

    PDF | Zimbabwe has recently experienced record hyperinflation of 80 billion percent a month. This paper uses new data from Zimbabwe to investigate money... | Find, read and cite all the research ...

  15. "Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe : case study and analysis of money velocity

    Hyperinflation, defined as inflation of over 50 percent month-over-month, in Zimbabwe began in March 2007. However, the economy has been plagued with annual inflation of over 20 percent since the early 1990s. Once regarded as the bread basket of Africa, Zimbabwe's political mismanagement has destroyed its own economic wellbeing. Were the government and central bank so ignorant as to lead the ...

  16. Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe: Background, Impact, and Policy

    In the case of Zimbabwe, the suspension of the domestic currency in 2009, alongside a partial change in government after the 2008 elections, had immediate beneficial effects. The levels of inflation quickly returned to single digits, GDP rebounded and confidence increased.

  17. (PDF) Zimbabwe Monetary Policy 1998-2012: From Hyperinflation to

    Mark Ellyne Zimbabwe's 2008 hyperinflation is said to be the second highest in recorded history, and provides an interesting case study of policy failure. We explore possible motivating factors behind the hyperinflation to understand why it happened and persisted for so long, and who benefited from it. The paper examines the exchange rate-inflation spiral and explains how a large parallel ...

  18. PDF OPTIMAL INFLATION FOR ZIMBABWE BY 1 2, K. Kupeta , P. S. Moyo and S

    a threshold level of inflation above which inflation is inimical to growth. The paper estimated threshold inflation for Zimbabwe during the stable period when Zimbabwe had its own currency, that is 1980 to 1997 and multicurrency system period, 2009 to 2017. The results suggest the threshold level of inflation of 8.7% for the period 1980 to 1997. As expected the optimal level of inflation falls ...

  19. The Effects of Inflation on Preparation of Financial Statements of the

    Abstract The effects of inflation on preparation of financial statements of the retail sector in Zimbabwe over recent decades. Inflation is broadly defined by many scholars as a general increase in prices and fall in the purchasing value of money. Although a considerable inflation knowledge base exists in Zimbabwean SMEs, there have been no comprehensive studies on inflation in retail ...

  20. Zimbabwe: Challenges and Policy Options after Hyperinflation

    This paper examines the challenges and policy options after hyperinflation in Zimbabwe. The paper reviews the pros and cons of alternative monetary regimes for Zimbabwe to succeed the current multicurrency system, which the authorities consider a temporary arrangement. The analysis suggests that some form of official dollarization has significant advantages. The paper also assesses ...

  21. Inflation, price controls, and fiscal adjustment in Zimbabwe

    Inflation, price controls, and fiscal adjustment in Zimbabwe. Global data and statistics, research and publications, and topics in poverty and development. Understanding Poverty. Research & Publications. Documents & Reports. This page in: English. Español.

  22. (PDF) Inflation Impact of an Exchange Rate Adjustment: The Case of

    The study examines and assesses the causes of inflation in the post-dollarized Zimbabwe. It employs time series econometric methodology based on monthly data to examine the probable factors influencing inflation in the post-dollarized Zimbabwe.