economics case studies wages and education

  • The Daily Dish

Serving economic news and views every morning.

The Week in Regulation

Analysis on the underemployment number in the monthly jobs report.

Weekly Checkup

Subscribe by topic, immigration, energy & environment, health care, technology & innovation, financial services.

economics case studies wages and education

At least one search term must be present.

economics case studies wages and education

June 4, 2019

The Economic Benefits of Educational Attainment

Douglas Holtz-Eakin, Tom Lee

Executive Summary

Education is vital for a highly skilled and productive labor force. This study seeks to quantify the relationships between additional educational attainment and employment opportunities, wage rates, and aggregate economic growth. We find that increasing education attainment would have powerful positive effects on the economy.

Specifically:

  • As individuals attain greater education, their probability of employment rises;
  • Greater education, including certification for those without a high-school or college degree, also increases workers’ ability to command higher wages; and
  • For every 1 percentage-point increase in the growth rate of the portion of a state’s population with at least a bachelor’s degree, the state’s real gross domestic product growth rate increases by about 0.08 percentage points. Consequently, if every state had increased its bachelor’s degree attainment growth rate by just 1 percentage point over the last decade, then nationwide economic growth would have increased by about $130.5 billion.

In sum: Greater post-secondary educational attainment of all types would not just increase employment opportunities and wages in the labor market, but would also spur widespread and stronger economic growth.

Introduction

Post-secondary education has clear benefits for those looking for a job: College-educated workers, for example, face lower unemployment and obtain higher wages than their less-educated counterparts. Unfortunately, education levels are not rising to match the economy’s demands. In the aftermath of the Great Recession, the unemployment rate has decreased from a high of 9.9 percent to about 3.8 percent. [1] Despite this overall improvement, the rise in U.S. education levels has not kept up with the rise in demand for highly skilled workers. This relative shortfall of skilled workers inhibits the ability of firms to meet demand, expand, and augment levels of productivity. For the state or national economy, the cascading effects of lower educational attainment translate into lower rates of aggregate growth.

In this study, we quantify the economic benefits of increasing education levels. Specifically, the study measures how attaining various levels of post-secondary education beyond a high-school diploma can positively affect workers’ chances of being employed and their wages. We then expand the scope of the analysis and examine the effect that raising the proportion of college graduates would have on the nation’s economy.

Compared to workers with at most high school diplomas, those with associate/vocational degrees for example, are about 8.47 percent more likely to be employed. Workers with associate/vocational degrees also make about 18.68 percent more than workers with at most high school diplomas.

With regard to impacts on economic growth, a 1 percentage-point increase in the growth rate of the portion of adult population with at least a bachelor’s degree (relative to the overall growth of the whole population) is associated with about a 0.08-percentage point increase in the real gross domestic product (GDP) growth rate. This association means that if each state raised the growth rate of the population with bachelor’s degrees by just 1 percentage point, then real GDP would increase by about $103.5 billion nationwide. We also compute the impact for each individual state.

These results suggest that there are real economic benefits that come from policy strategies to increase the accessibility of additional education.

Data and Methods

At the heart of this study is the relationship between a worker’s educational level, his or her chances of being employed, and the wages that employment commands. To investigate this relationship, we used data from the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Current Population Survey (CPS) supplemental data from March 2018.

Our first focus is on the link between a respondent’s employment status and educational attainment. We included indicator variables for each measure of educational attainment, with high school graduates being the base category. Specifically, we have binary variables for dropouts, dropouts with certifications, high-school graduates with certifications, some college, some college with certifications, associate/vocational-degree holders, bachelor’s degree holders, master’s degree holders, and doctorate degree holders. Notice that this approach measures how the attainment of a certification (e.g. a welding certification) improves the employment prospects of those who have not attained a college education. In addition, our empirical techniques also control for gender, race, ethnicity, and whether a respondent lives in a metropolitan area. [2]

We adopt a logit model and account for heteroscedasticity [3] and other possibilities by using robust standard errors to estimate our model. We also have included binary variables to control for unobservable differences between states (state fixed effects). (For the model, see Equation 1 in the Appendix.)

The second relationship of interest is between wages and education. Our dependent variable is the natural logarithm of weekly earnings of workers. We again included binary variables for each level of education attainment, given that high school graduates are the base category. In addition to the same controls used in the above model, we included controls for industry of worker, occupation, union membership/representation, immigration status, school enrollment status, marital status, disability, and number of children. The binaries for each state are also included. (For the model, see Equation 2 in the Appendix.)

Finally, to quantify the effect of increasing educational attainment on the U.S. economy, we compiled panel data from 2007 to 2017 for the 50 states and the District of Columbia. We used a fixed-effects model to control for all unobservable state and time differences. Our dependent variable is the real GDP growth rate and our independent variable of interest is the change in the proportion of a state’s population (aged 25 and over) that has at least a bachelor’s degree. We experimented with a measure of the fraction of the state’s population that attained an associate degree but found no statistically reliable relationship. [4]

One can think of the basic relationship as being between the log-level of output and the level of human capital, which is transformed into growth rates. From this perspective, it is important to control for other time-varying components of human capital. We include the state’s high-school graduation rate, average score on math portion of the National Assessment of Educational Progress, proportion of the labor force in the manufacturing sector, and proportion of employed workers represented by unions. We proxied additional impacts on demand using average student debt of degree holders. We also use robust standard errors to account for possible heteroscedasticity in our data. (For the model, see Equation 3 in the Appendix.)

The results of estimating Equation 1 are reported in Table 1 (below). Because logit models are based on logged odds, their coefficients can be difficult to interpret. Therefore, we have also calculated the average marginal effects (AME) of each variable and included them as well. Only the variables of interest have been reported to conserve space.

The key result is that various levels of education beyond high school diplomas lead to statistically significant increased opportunities in the labor market.

The results of Table 1 are relative to workers with at most high school diplomas or GEDs. The far right column, labeled Effect of Education on Employment Status, provides the most relevant results. For example, the top two rows indicate that:

  • A high school dropout is 29.8 percent less likely to be employed than a worker with at most a high school diploma; and
  • A high school dropout with a professional certification is 19.36 percent more likely to be employed than a high school graduate without a professional certification.
Table 1: Dependent Variable: Employed?

Dropout -1.56***

(.022)

-29.8%
Dropout w/ Cert. 1.02***

(.107)

19.36%
HS Grad w/ Cert. 1.37***

(.024)

26.03%
Some College -0.02

(.019)

-0.37%
Some College w/ Cert. 0.13**

(.058)

2.51%
Assoc./Voc. 0.44***

(.023)

8.47%
Bachelor 0.68***

(.018)

12.96%
Mast/Prof. 0.68***

(.024)

12.98%
Doctorate 0.79***

(.053)

15.16%
Constant 1.84***

(.049)

NA
Pseudo R 0.1664 NA
*** < 0.01, ** < 0.05, *p < 0.10

Further, those with bachelor’s degrees are 12.96 percent more likely to be employed than those with at most a high school diploma or GED. Notably, this is actually less significant than the employment impacts of having a professional certification. Workers that earn higher than a bachelor’s degree are between 12.98 percent and 15.16 percent more likely to be employed than those with at most a high school diploma or GED. Note that the effect of having some college is statistically insignificant (or in other words, inconclusive) and should not be seriously considered.

Similarly, our estimated version of Equation 2 shows a statistically significant relationship between the education variables and the natural log of weekly earnings. The results of this model are reported in Table 2. Because the specification is in log-levels, we can interpret our coefficients as the percentage impact on weekly earnings.

The results of Table 2 are relative to workers with at most high school diplomas or GEDs. Again, the far-right column provides the interpreted results. The top two rows indicate that

  • A high school dropout will make about 35.18 percent less than a worker with at most a high school diploma or GED; and
  • A high school dropout with a certification will make about 19.59 percent more than a worker with at most a high school diploma or GED.
Table 2: Dependent Variable: Natural Log of Weekly Earnings

Dropout -0.3518***

(.0352)

-35.18%
Dropout w/ Cert. 0.1959*

(.105)

19.59%
HS Grad w/ Cert. 0.1015***

(.023)

10.15%
Some College 0.0237

(.027)

2.37%
Some College w/ Cert. 0.1649***

(.049)

16.49%
Assoc./Voc. 0.1868***

(.030)

18.68%
Bachelor 0.4467***

(.025)

44.67%
Mast/Prof. 0.6362***

(.034)

63.62%
Doctorate Degree 0.8265***

(.060)

82.65%
Constant 7.0421***

(.080)

NA
Pseudo R 0.3321 NA
*** < 0.01, ** < 0.05, *p < 0.10

Those with an associate degree earn on average 18.68 percent more per week than those with at most a high school diploma, and for those attaining a bachelor’s degree that figure jumps to 44.7 percent. Workers that earn higher than a bachelor’s degree make about 63.6 percent to 81.7 percent more than those with at most a GED/high-school diploma. Note the effect of having some college is statistically insignificant (or in other words, inconclusive) and should not be seriously considered.

Thus far, we have shown that there are strong economic incentives for individuals to pursue not only college degrees, but also other forms of post-secondary education and certification. These incentives include greater probabilities of employment at higher wages. We now turn to the relationship that policymakers may also care about – educational attainment and economic performance.

The estimated results of Equation 3 (Table 3, below) show a significant relationship between the fraction of the population that has a bachelor’s degree and economic prosperity. Specifically, our estimated coefficient indicates that increasing the growth rate of the population with at least a bachelor’s degree (relative to the population as a whole) is associated with an increase in a state’s GDP growth rate by an average of 0.08 percentage points. The real GDP growth rate for 2018 was 2.9 percent. With an additional 0.08 percentage points in real GDP growth, the real GDP growth rate would have been about 2.98 percent. Using the growth rate of the population with associate/vocational degrees did not result in a statistically significant relationship with real GDP growth. Because of this inconclusive relationship, we have not included that model.

In terms of interpreting the coefficients of our model, looking at the top two rows,

  • A 1 percentage-point increase in the growth rate of a state’s population with bachelor’s degrees is associated with about a 0.08 percentage-point increase in the state’s real GDP growth rate; and
  • A 1 percentage-point increase in the growth rate of a state’s high school graduation rate is associated with about a 0.05-percentage point increase in the state’s real GDP growth rate. (See past AAF research for more on growth impacts of higher graduation rates).

Table 3: Dependent Variable: RGDP Growth

Proportion with Bachelor’s 0.08*

(.045)

High School Graduation Rate 0.05

(.044)

Average Student Debt 0.02

(.017)

Score on Math portion of NAEP -0.08

(.067)

Population 0.16

(.107)

Proportion of Labor Force in Manufacturing 0.12*

(.064)

Percent of Employed Workers Represented by a Union -0.003

(.007)

Constant 0.007

(.005)

R Overall

 

0.2757

 

*** < 0.01, ** < 0.05, *p < 0.10

Implications

Our results indicate that there are broad economic benefits to more people attaining a college education, associate degree, vocational school training, or other professional certification. In this section, we spell out those benefits.

Using the results from Tables 1 and 2, consider a scenario where every member of the non-institutional civilian population who has at most a high school diploma or GED received an associate or vocational degree. The results suggest that 5.9 million more people would be employed. Of these 5.9 million people, their annual wages would increase by about $291 billion, in aggregate. In addition, of the already-employed persons with high school diplomas or GEDs who now hypothetically have an associate or vocational degree, their annual wages would increase by about $301 billion, in aggregate. Combining these figures, if all members of the non-institutional civilian population that had at most high school diplomas or GEDs now had an associate or vocational degree, their annual wages would increase by nearly $600 billion, in aggregate. Table 4 contains these figures for each level of education, considering high school diploma or GED to be the base category.

Note that the Some College column is statistically insignificant (or in other words, inconclusive) from the regression model. Even though the effect has been estimated to be negative, we cannot confidently believe in those figures.

Table 4: Employment and Wage Implications of Educational Attainment

Employment Change
Employment (Millions) 13.5 18.2 -0.2 1.8 5.9 9.1 9.1 10.6
Wages Total (Billions) $670.6 $830.3 -$10.9 $84.7 $291.1 $543.0 $615.3 $801.6
Wage Change of People With Jobs
Average Wage $156 $81 $19 $132 $149 $357 $508 $660
Total Wages (Billions) $315.8 $163.6 $38.2 $265.8 $301.2 $720.2 $1,025.7 $1,332.5
Total (Billions) $986.4 $993.9 $27.4 $350.5 $592.3 $1,263.2 $1,641.0 $2,134.2

Similarly, using the results from our panel data model (Equation 3, reported in Table 3), we can estimate the effect on the economy of increasing the growth rate of the proportion of a state’s population with at least a bachelor’s degree. From 2010 to 2017, the actual real GDP growth rate was about 2.11 percent. Had every state increased the growth rate at which people receive bachelor’s degrees by 1 percentage point for the past decade, the growth rate would have increased from about 2.11 percent to about 2.19 percent, which translates to about a $103.5 billion increase in real GDP. Of course, the impacts will show up in state economies, too. These estimates can be found in the map, below.

State RGDP GRAlternate GRAlternate RGDP - Actual RGDP ($)
AL0.80.891134
AK-0.5-0.41312
AZ0.022.151726
AR1.041.13669
CA3.263.3414798
CO2.892.981864
CT-0.5-0.411424
DC1.521.61714
DE0.90.98376
FL2.052.135133
GA2.392.472959
HI1.621.71464
ID2.112.19389
IL11.094377
IN1.211.31882
IA1.871.87986
KS1.371.46869
KY1.021.11084
LA-1.24-1.161361
ME0.480.56328
MD1.491.582122
MA2.072.162848
MI1.942.032669
MN1.781.871879
MS0.020.11594
MO0.310.391630
MT1.311.39260
NE1.881.96649
NV1.491.57835
NH1.631.72434
NJ0.810.893216
NM0.640.72536
NY1.561.648260
NC1.61.682827
ND4.354.44289
OH1.811.893441
OK2.632.711103
OR2.993.071196
PA1.711.794087
RI0.540.63315
SC2.292.371156
SD1.791.87265
TN2.412.51825
TX3.133.229291
UT2.842.93865
VT0.720.81174
VA0.840.922727
WA3.373.462759
WV0.440.52417
WI1.421.51709
WY0.41-0.32230

Education is essential to a highly skilled and productive labor force, and increasing the rate at which people graduate from college would have powerful effects on the economy. This study finds that for every 1 percentage-point increase in the portion of a state’s population with at least a bachelor’s degree, the state’s real GDP growth rate increases by about 0.08 percentage points. Consequently, if every state had increased its bachelor’s degree-attainment growth rate by just 1 percentage point over the last decade, then nationwide country economic growth would have increased by about $130.5 billion.

Even for those who do not obtain a bachelor’s degree, the employment and wage impacts of obtaining a certification, associate degree, or vocational qualification are significant enough to merit increased policy attention. In fact, each of these levels of post-secondary training have a greater impact on a person’s wages and prospects for employment on average than if they had attended a four-year college without obtaining a bachelor’s degree. Thus, greater post-secondary educational attainment of all types would not only increase employment opportunities and wages in the labor market, but would also spur widespread and stronger economic growth.

Equation 1 corresponds with Table 1.

We adopt a logit model and account for heteroscedasticity and other possibilities by using robust standard errors to estimate our model. We also have included binary variables to control for unobservable differences between states (state fixed effects).

Prob(employment) = β 0 + β 1 ( dropout ) + β 2 ( certdrop ) + β 3 ( cert ) + β 4 ( some ) + β 5 ( asocvoc ) + β 6 ( certsome ) + β 7 ( ba ) + β 8 ( mastprof ) + β 9 ( fem ) + β 10 ( age ) + β 11 ( race) + β 12 ( hisp ) + β 13 ( urban ) + β 14 ( Alabama ) + … + β 65 ( Wyoming ) + ε

Equation 2 corresponds with Table 2.

ln(Weekly Earnings) = β 0 + β 1 ( dropout ) + β 2 ( certdrop ) + β 3 ( cert ) + β 4 ( some ) + β 5 ( certsome ) + β 6 ( some ) + β 7 ( certsome ) + β 8 ( asocvoc ) + β 9 ( ba) + β 10 ( mastprof ) + β 11 ( doc ) + β 12 ( fem ) + β 13 ( age ) + β 14 ( race ) + β 15 ( hisp ) + β 16 ( urban ) + β 17 ( indust ) + β 18 ( occu ) + β 19

Equation 3 corresponds with Table 3.

Finally, to quantify the effect of increasing educational attainment on the U.S. economy, we compiled panel data from 2007 to 2017 for the 50 states and the District of Columbia. We used a fixed-effects model to control for all unobservable state and time differences. Our dependent variable is the real GDP growth rate and our independent variable of interest is the change in the proportion of a state’s population (aged 25 and over) that has at least a bachelor’s degree. We experimented with a measure of the fraction of the state’s population that attained an associate degree but found no statistically reliable relationship.

Real GDP Growth i = β 0 + β 1 (bag i ) + β 2 (gradrateg i ) + β 3 (avgstudebtg i ) + β 4 (mathscoreg i ) + β 5 (populg i ) + β 6 (manuRatiog i ) + β 7 (percuniong i ) + β 8 (oNine) + … + β 16 (seventeen) + ε

[1] https://data.bls.gov/timeseries/LNS14000000

[2] Summary Statistics are available from the authors upon request.

[3] Random variables are heteroscedastic when their subpopulations have unequal variability across different values of those variables. Heteroscedasticity can invalidate hypothesis tests.

[4] These results are available from the authors upon request.

Daily Dish Signup Sidebar

  • Get the Daily Dish *

economics case studies wages and education

Douglas Holtz-Eakin

Douglas Holtz-Eakin is the President of the American Action Forum.

economics case studies wages and education

Former Data and Policy Analyst

Tom Lee is a former Data and Policy Analyst at the American Action Forum.

The American Action Forum is a 21st century center-right policy institute providing actionable research and analysis to solve America’s most pressing policy challenges.

Economic Indicators: Topline Numbers

Consumer price index, m/m change:, y/y change:.

Measures the change in prices of all goods and services purchased for consumption by urban households.

Core Consumer Price Index

Consumer Price Index excluding food and energy.

Core Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index

A measure of prices paid for goods and services excluding food and energy; the Federal Reserve’s preferred measure of inflation.

Producer Price Index

Measures the change in selling prices received by domestic producers of goods and services.

Initial Jobless Claims

Week ending June 15, 2024

4-week Moving Average:

Weekly unemployment insurance claims reported by each state’s unemployment insurance program offices.

ISM Services Index

A level above 50 indicates expansion

ISM Manufacturing Index

Consumer sentiment.

The core questions cover three broad areas of consumer sentiment: personal finances, business conditions, and buying conditions.

ADP Employment:

Change in u.s. private employment:.

Measures change in private-sector employment using ADP payroll data covering more than half a million companies with more than 25 million employees.

Nondefense Capital Goods Orders Excluding Aircraft

A new order is a communication of an intention to buy for immediate or future delivery.

New Residential Housing Starts

Privately owned housing starts; seasonally adjusted at an annual rate.

  • Original article
  • Open access
  • Published: 23 January 2018

Does education raise productivity and wages equally? The moderating role of age and gender

  • Stephan Kampelmann 1 ,
  • François Rycx 1 , 3 , 4 , 5 ,
  • Yves Saks 2 &
  • Ilan Tojerow 1 , 3  

IZA Journal of Labor Economics volume  7 , Article number:  1 ( 2018 ) Cite this article

30k Accesses

37 Citations

17 Altmetric

Metrics details

We estimate the impact of education on productivity, wage costs and productivity-wage gaps (i.e. profits) using Belgian linked panel data. Findings highlight that educational credentials have a stronger impact on productivity than on wage costs. Firms’ profitability is found to rise when lower educated workers are substituted by higher educated ones. This effect is found to be more pronounced among younger workers and women. Findings thus suggest that the productivity to wage cost ratio of low-educated workers is detrimental to their employability, especially when young or female. They also support the existence of a glass ceiling on women’s career development.

1 Introduction

Human capital theory (Becker 1964 ) posits that (i) education develops skills that make workers more productive and (ii) wage differentials reflect differences in productivity. Accordingly, more highly educated workers would earn higher wages ceteris paribus simply because they are more productive than their less-educated counterparts. This explanation of pay inequality has been challenged by empirical and theoretical work on labour markets. Indeed, a range of labour market theories hypothesise sources of inequality other than labour productivity, such as collective action, labour market institutions or the use of power and authority to obtain economic advantages (Berg 1981 ; Kalleberg and Sørensen 1979 ; Weeden 2002 ). Although each of these theories on inequality focuses on distinct social processes, they appear to have in common that they associate labour market inequality at least implicitly to an element of ‘unearned’ or ‘unjust’ allocation of resources to dominant groups. On the other hand, economists have also developed explanations of differences between productivity and wages without abandoning the assumptions of individual rationality and profit-maximising firms. In this literature, productivity-wage gaps are thought to be rational strategies of firms to address a range of market distortions (Lazear and Shaw 2007 ).

The abundance of theories on education-driven productivity-wage gaps is not matched by a corresponding body of empirical literature. Indeed, very few studies have actually examined how the educational composition of the labour force affects firm productivity (Galindo-Rueda and Haskel 2005 ; Haegeland and Klette 1999 ; Haltiwanger et al. 1999 ; Moretti 2004 ). Footnote 1 Moreover, the evidence on whether education raises productivity and wages equally is very thin, Footnote 2 inconclusive and subject to various possible econometric biases (Hellerstein and Neumark 2004 ; Ilmakunnas and Maliranta 2005 ; Van Biesebroeck 2011 ). The endogeneity of education and the presence of firm-level time-invariant unobserved heterogeneity are for instance seldom controlled for. Most estimates regarding the education-productivity nexus and the existence of possible education-driven productivity-wage gaps are thus potentially inconsistent. What is more, to our knowledge, no study has tried to assess whether the education-productivity-wage nexus varies with the composition of the firm’s workforce in terms of age and gender. Yet, numerous arguments (notably related to information asymmetries, social norms or labour market regulations) suggest that this is probably the case. As an example, it could be noted that labour market regulations (such as minimum wages or unemployment benefits) essentially affect the lower end of the earnings distribution. As a result, these regulations are more likely to lead to a ‘wage-compression effect’ (i.e. a distribution of wage costs by educational groups that is more compressed than the education-productivity profile) among workers earning lower wages, e.g. younger workers (Cardoso 2010 ). As regards workers’ gender, given that upper management jobs are mainly occupied by men, tournament theory (Lazear and Rosen 1981 ) for instance suggests that high-educated men have a greater likelihood to be paid above their marginal productivity. These examples, among others, suggest that workers’ age and gender may have a substantial effect on the (mis)alignment of wages and productivity across educational groups. Footnote 3

The aim of this paper is threefold. First, we put the relationship between the educational composition of the workforce and firm productivity to an updated test, using Belgian linked employer-employee panel data for the years 1999–2010. These data offer several advantages. The panel covers a large part of the private sector, provides accurate information on average productivity (i.e. the average value added per hour worked) and allows us to control for a wide range of worker and firm characteristics. It also enables us to address important methodological issues, such as firm-level time-invariant heterogeneity, measurement errors, reverse causality, feedback effects and state dependence of firm productivity. Indeed, early studies using the Hellerstein and Neumark approach ‘have been criticized mainly due to the potential endogeneity’ in the explanatory variables that have been studied (Bartolucci 2013 ), which can be a result of these issues. To do so, we rely on the generalised method of moments (GMM) estimator. Footnote 4 A second objective is to examine whether education increases productivity and wage costs equally (i.e. to extend the analysis to productivity-wage gaps). Finally, our study provides first evidence on whether the alignment between productivity and wage costs across educational levels depends on the characteristics of workers, i.e. their age and gender.

Research questions addressed in this paper are very important for economic policy. The labour market situation of low-educated workers is particularly critical in most industrialised countries. This is also the case in Belgium (Eurostat 2016a ). The unemployment rate in Belgium among the low-educated (i.e. people with less than upper secondary education) is three times larger than that among tertiary educated workers (16.4 vs. 4.7% in 2014). As regards the employment rate, it is found to be more than 40 percentage points lower among the former group of workers (37.3 versus 81.9% in 2014). Footnote 5 Various theories, including skilled-biased technological change and competition from low-wage countries, have been put forward to explain this phenomenon (Cahuc and Zylberberg 2014 ). A key argument here is that low-educated workers are too costly relative to their added value. As a result, firms are willing to substitute low-educated workers by capital, to outsource part of their activities to cheap-labour countries and (especially in the case of excess labour supply) to hire more educated workers as their productivity to wage cost ratio is more favourable. Footnote 6

Despite the fact that alternative theories (based on tournaments, internal decision-making processes of organisations, monopsony or monitoring issues) suggest that low-educated workers might actually not be too costly relative to their marginal products (Lazear and Rosen 1981 ; Bebchuk and Fried 2003 ; Osterman et al. 2009 ), most policies aiming to increase the employability of low-educated people in the OECD area either try to foster the latters’ productivity (e.g. through specific training programmes) and/or to decrease their wage cost (e.g. through reduced payroll taxes). Belgium is no exception in this respect. Indeed, it is among the highest spenders for active labour market policies in Europe (Eurostat 2016b ) and reductions in employers’ and personnel social security contributions (notably targeted on the low-skilled) represent around 1.8% of GDP (Belgian federal government 2015 ). While these policies are quite standard to improve the labour market prospects of low-educated people, their effectiveness is still highly controversial (Heckman et al. 1999 ; Cahuc and Carcillo 2012 ; Kluve 2010 ; Card et al. 2010 ). This is notably due to the fact that it remains unclear whether education-induced productivity gains are well aligned with corresponding wage cost differentials. In particular, more evidence is needed on whether the productivity to wage cost ratio of low-educated people is really critical for their employability. The objective of this paper is to improve our understanding of these issues with a specific focus on workers’ age and gender.

The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. The following two sections, respectively, describe our methodology, estimation techniques and data set. We then analyse the impact of the composition of the workforce in term of education on productivity, wages, and productivity-wage gaps and end with a discussion of the results and a conclusion.

2 Set-up of the analysis

2.1 methodology.

The test developed in this article is based on the estimation of a value added function and a wage cost equation at the firm level. The value added function yields parameter estimates for the average impact of workers with different educational levels, while the wage equation estimates the respective impact of each educational group on the average wage bill paid by the firm. Given that both equations are estimated with the same set of firms, educational categories and covariates, the parameters for output elasticities and wages can be compared so that conclusions on educational productivity-wage gaps can be drawn. This technique was pioneered by Hellerstein et al. ( 1999a , 1999b ) and refined by van Ours and Stoeldraijer ( 2011 ) among others. It is now standard in the literature on the productivity and wage effects of labour heterogeneity (see e.g. Cardoso et al. 2011 ; Devicienti et al. ( 2017 ); Garnero et al. 2014 ; Giuliano et al. 2017 ; Göbel and Zwick 2012 ; Ilmakunnas and Maliranta 2005 ; Mahlberg et al. 2013 ; Nielen and Schiersch 2014 ).

The estimated firm-level productivity and wage cost equations are the following:

The dependent variable in Eq. (1) is firm i ’s hourly value added, obtained by dividing the total value added (at factor costs) of firm i in period t by the total number of hours worked (taking into account paid overtime hours) that have been declared for the same period. The dependent variable in Eq. (2) is firm i ’s average wage bill (including payroll taxes and variable pay components, such as wage premia for overtime, weekend or night work, performance bonuses and other premia). It is obtained by dividing the firm’s total wage cost by the total number of hours worked. Hence, the dependent variables in the estimated equations are firm averages of value added and wage costs (net of social security payroll tax cuts) on an hourly basis.

The main independent variables are the shares of hours worked by each educational category in total hours worked, Education j,i,t . This is a better employment indicator than the number of employees in each category since it takes into account educational differences in working time. We split the employees of a firm into three educational groups (i.e. at most lower secondary education, at most higher secondary education, and tertiary education, respectively) and consider the share of workers with at most lower secondary education as our reference category. As a robustness test, we also consider more detailed educational groups including up to seven categories.

In addition to the shares of workers by educational level in total hours worked, we also include the vector X i,t. . It contains a set of variables controlling for observable worker, job and firm characteristics. More precisely, it includes the share of the workforce within a firm that (i) has at least 10 years of tenure, (ii) is younger than 30 and older than 49 years, respectively, (iii) is female, (iv) works part-time, (v) occupies blue-collar jobs, (vi) has a fixed-term employment contract, and (vi) is apprentice or under contract with a temporary employment agency. X i,t also comprises the natural logarithm of firm size (i.e. the number of full-time equivalent workers), the natural logarithm of capital stock per worker, Footnote 7 the level of collective wage bargaining Footnote 8 (1 dummy), sectoral affiliation (8 dummies), the region where the firm is located (2 dummies), and 11 year dummies. Footnote 9

Estimating Eqs. (1) and (2) allows gauging the effect of education on firm productivity and wage costs, but it does not allow testing directly whether the difference between the added value and wage cost coefficients for a given educational group is statistically significant. A simple method to obtain a test for the significance of productivity-wage gaps has been proposed by van Ours and Stoeldraijer ( 2011 ). This method boils down to estimating Eq. (3):

in which the gap between firm i ’s log hourly value added and log hourly wage costs (i.e. the log of the ratio between value added and wage costs) is regressed on the same set of explanatory variables as in Eqs. (1) and (2). This produces coefficients for the educational variables and directly measures the size and significance of their respective productivity-pay gaps.

In light of the so-called persistence of profits literature (see e.g. Bou and Satorra 2007 ), there are strong theoretical arguments for adding a dynamic element to Eqs. (1) to (3). The assumption of persistent productivity and wages both at the industry and firm level also finds some support in the literature. According to Syverson ( 2011 : 326), different studies ‘documented, virtually without exception, enormous and persistent measured productivity differences across producers, even within narrowly defined industries’. Large parts of these productivity differences are still hard to explain. The persistence of wage costs is also highlighted in the literature (see e.g. Fuss and Wintr 2009 ). Wage stickiness is notably the outcome of labour market institutions, adjustment costs and efficiency wages’ motives. It is therefore standard in the literature to use dynamic panel data methods such as those proposed by Arellano and Bond ( 1991 ) to overcome lag dependency. Accordingly, many papers rely on the dynamic generalised method of moments (GMM) to estimate the impact of workforce and job characteristics on productivity and/or labour costs (see e.g. Cardoso et al. 2011 ; Giuliano et al. 2017 ; Göbel and Zwick 2012 ; Mahlberg et al. 2013 ; Nielen and Schiersch 2014 ; van Ours and Stoeldraijer 2011 ).

2.2 Estimation techniques

Equations (1) to (3) have been estimated with four different methods: pooled ordinary least squares (OLS), a fixed-effects (FE) model and the GMM estimator developed by Arellano and Bover ( 1995 ) and Blundell and Bond ( 1998 ). For the added value function, we also follow Levinsohn and Petrin ( 2003 ) and provide results based on their (LP) estimator, which is particularly well-suited for panels with small t and big N , controls for endogeneity by using the firms’ intermediate inputs (i.e. inputs such as energy, raw material, semi-finished goods and services that are typically subtracted from gross output to obtain added value) to proxy for unobserved productivity shocks. The intuition is that firms respond to time-varying productivity shocks observed by managers (and not by econometricians) through the adjustment of their intermediate inputs. Put differently, profit-maximising firms react to positive (negative) productivity shocks by increasing (decreasing) their output, which requires more (less) intermediate inputs.

The OLS estimator is based on the cross-sectional variability between firms and the longitudinal variability within firms over time. However, this OLS estimator suffers from not accounting for firm-specific time-invariant characteristics that are not measured in micro-level surveys (e.g. an advantageous location, firm-specific assets such as patent ownership, or other firm idiosyncrasies).

The conventional way to remove unobserved firm characteristics that remained unchanged during the observation period is by estimating a fixed effects (FE) model. This boils down to estimate a within differentiated model, i.e. a model where the mean of each variable has been subtracted from the initial values. This approach cannot be applied for the firms in our sample: the variable of interest, i.e. the shares of workers by level of education, does not show sufficient variation over time to be a useful explanatory variable for firm-level wages or productivity after mean differencing (see e.g. Wooldridge 2010 ). Moreover, neither pooled OLS nor the FE estimator address the potential endogeneity of our explanatory variables. Footnote 10 Yet, as highlighted by Gautier et al. ( 2002 : 523), ‘employers might exploit cyclical downturns to improve the average skill level of their work force’. To put it differently, there might be some cyclical ‘crowding out’, namely a process by which during recessions—because of excess labour supply—highly educated workers take the jobs that could be occupied by less-educated ones. This assumption, supported empirically for certain countries including Belgium (Cockx and Dejemeppe 2002 ; Dolado et al. 2000 ), suggests that the share of more educated workers within firms may increase as a result of lower labour productivity (and vice versa). We have performed a direct endogeneity test on the educational variables in our sample and indeed reject the null hypothesis that our main variables of interest can actually be treated as exogenous. Footnote 11 To control for this endogeneity issue, in addition to temporal persistence in the dependent variable (firm productivity, wage costs or profits) and firm fixed unobserved heterogeneity, we estimate Eqs. (1) to (3) with the dynamic system GMM (GMM-SYS).

The GMM-SYS approach implies to simultaneously estimate a system of two equations (respectively in level and in first differences) and rely on internal instruments to control for endogeneity. More precisely, educational variables Footnote 12 are instrumented by their lagged levels in the differenced equation and by their lagged differences in the level equation. Footnote 13 The implicit assumption is that changes (the level) in (of) the dependent variable—productivity, salary costs or profits—in one period are uncorrelated with lagged levels (differences) of the latter. Moreover, changes (levels) in (of) educational variables are assumed to be reasonably correlated to their past levels (changes). Footnote 14

One advantage of the system GMM is that time-invariant explanatory variables can be included among the regressors, while they typically disappear in difference GMM. Asymptotically, the inclusion of these variables does not affect the estimates of the other regressors because instruments in the level equation (i.e. lagged differences of educational variables) are expected to be orthogonal to all time-invariant variables (Roodman 2009 ). To examine the validity of our estimates, we apply Hansen’s ( 1982 ) and Arellano and Bond’s ( 1991 ) tests. The first is a test for overidentification which allows to test the validity of the instruments. The second is a test for autocorrelation, where the null hypothesis assumes no second order autocorrelation in the first differenced errors. The non-rejection of the two tests is required in order to assume that our estimates are reliable.

The adoption of a dynamic GMM specification aims to account for the persistency in firm-level profits, wage costs and productivity. It is also likely to improve the identification of the parameters of interest (even though the coefficient on the lagged dependent variable is not a central issue in the analysis). Indeed, as illustrated by Bond ( 2002 ), the use of a dynamic model is necessary to obtain consistent results when estimating a production function with serially correlated productivity shocks and explanatory variables that are correlated to these shocks. While serial correlation of productivity shocks may arise if for instance the effects of demand shocks are only partially captured by the industry-specific control variables (Hempell, 2005 ), the responsiveness of input factors to productivity shocks may be explained by the abovementioned endogeneity issue. Interestingly, the inclusion of the lagged dependent variable in the OLS, fixed-effects and system GMM specifications also provides an ad hoc test for the appropriateness of the latter. As outlined by Roodman ( 2009 ), this test consists in checking whether or not the regression coefficient on the lagged dependent variable obtained with system GMM falls between the OLS and fixed effects estimates. Footnote 15

3 Data and descriptive statistics

We use a combination of two large datasets covering the years 1999–2010. The first is the ‘Structure of Earnings Survey’ (SES), carried out by Statistics Belgium. It covers all firms that are operating in Belgium, employ more than 10 workers and have economic activities within sections C to K of the NACE Rev. 1 nomenclature. Footnote 16 This survey gathers information on firms’ characteristics (e.g. sector, region where the firm is located, number of workers, level of collective wage bargaining) as well as information on workers’ characteristics (e.g. age, education, tenure, paid hours, gender, occupation, employment contract). However, the SES does not provide any financial information. It has thus been merged with a firm-level survey, namely the ‘Structure of Business Survey’ (SBS), also carried out by Statistics Belgium. This survey provides financial information (e.g. firm-level wage cost, value added and gross operating surplus per hour worked). The coverage of the SBS differs from that of the SES in that it does not cover the whole financial sector (NACE J) but only Other Financial Intermediation (NACE 652) and Activities Auxiliary to Financial Intermediation (NACE 67). The merger of the SES and SBS datasets has been carried out by Statistics Belgium using firms’ social security numbers.

Information in the SES refers to the month of October of each year, while data in the SBS are measured over entire calendar years, i.e. from January to December. To avoid running a regression where information on the dependent variable (collected for the entire year) precedes the recording of the explanatory variables (collected in October), all explanatory variables in Eqs. (1) to (3) have been lagged by 1 year. This way, information on educational variables is recorded in October in year t and used to explain firm-level productivity, wage costs and productivity-wage gaps during the calendar year t + 1 . The imperfect synchronisation of the SBS and SES data might introduce some fuzziness into our estimates since we cannot exclude the occurrence of external events influencing firm performance in the intermediate period. This concern could only be completely eliminated if we had firm-level information on educational variables for the entire calendar year. This being said, even if this information were available, there is a compelling argument for using asynchronised information on educational variables: it is difficult to conceive how changes in shares of workers by educational level could generate immediate effects notably on firm productivity and productivity-wage gaps. Potential effects are indeed more likely to occur after a certain adjustment period. The slightly asynchronised use of SBS and SES is therefore arguably the best option in light of data availability and firm performance dynamics.

As a consequence, our sample contains firms that are observed in at least two consecutive years and thus over-represents medium-sized and large firms since the sampling percentages for each firm in our dataset increase with the size of the latter. Footnote 17 Next, we exclude workers and firms for which data are missing or inaccurate. Footnote 18 Finally, we drop firms with fewer than 10 observations (i.e. with information on less than 10 employees in a given year), because the use of average values at the firm level requires a suitable number of observations. Footnote 19  Firm-level averages used in the regression analysis below are computed by taking into account the sampling weights that ensure the representativeness of the employee sample. Since we have to delete observations with missing information for some variables and firms that are not observed in at least two consecutive years, we do not work with the complete sample of the SES-SBS. It is therefore worthwhile to verify whether the composition of the sample in terms of educational credentials is affected by the reduction in the sample size. Appendix 9 shows average values and standard deviations for average firm shares of three levels of educational attainment in (a) the complete sample, (b) the sample for which all variables of interest are non-missing and (c) the final sample with non-missing information and firms that are observed in at least two consecutive years. We conclude from this exercise that both the average values and the standard deviations are relatively stable across sub-samples. Our final sample covering the period 1999–2010 consists of an unbalanced panel of 6714 firm-year-observations from 1844 firms. In summary, our sample is therefore representative of all medium-sized and large firms in the Belgian private sector, with the exception of large parts of the financial sector (NACE J) and the electricity, gas and water supply industry (NACE E), because (a) both the SES and SBS are based on official surveys of administrative data collected from a large representative sample of the Belgian private sector, (b) we drop small firms for which we have less than 10 employee observations and (c) we drop firms from the public sector as well as large parts of sectors NACE J and NACE E, which are underrepresented in the data.

Descriptive statistics of selected variables are presented in Table  1 . We observe that firms have a mean value added per hour worked of 66.19 EUR and that workers’ mean hourly wage cost stands at 33.34 EUR. Footnote 20 Average hourly profits (i.e. gross operating surplus) are equal to 32.85 EUR. As regards the educational composition of the labour force, in our sample, the share of workers with at most lower secondary education stands at around 30%, the fraction of workers with higher secondary educational attainment reaches approximately 42%, and about 28% of employees have a degree of tertiary education. The share of high-educated (low-educated) workers is approximately 3 percentage points higher (lower) than in the raw SES-SBS sample, suggesting that high-educated (low-educated) workers are somewhat over-represented (under-represented) in the sample we use in our regression analysis.

Employees in our sample are essentially concentrated in the manufacturing industry (58%), wholesale and retail trade, repair of motor vehicles, motorcycles and personal and household goods (12%), construction (10%), real estate, renting and business activities (10%), and transport, storage and communication (6%). Moreover, firms employ on average 26% of women, 62% of prime-age workers (i.e. workers aged between 30 and 49 years), 40% of employees with less than 10 years of tenure, 53% of blue-collar workers, 11% of part-time workers, and 3% of workers with a fixed-term employment contract. Also noteworthy is that 57% of workers are employed in Flanders, 28% in Wallonia and 15% in Brussels. Finally, as regards collective bargaining, Table  1 shows that 32% of workers are covered by a firm-level collective agreement (in addition to an industry-level agreement).

4.1 Benchmark estimates

Given the abovementioned econometric issues associated with pooled OLS and FE estimates, we directly report findings based on the dynamic GMM-SYS estimator. Footnote 21 For the value added equation, we also provide estimation results using the more structural Levinson-Petrin method, which corroborate the GMM-SYS estimates for this equation. Table  2 shows the impact of shares of workers by level of education on hourly productivity, wage costs and productivity-pay gaps Footnote 22 at the firm level. Workers have been split in three educational groups according to whether they had (i) at most lower secondary education (low-educated workers), (ii) an upper secondary educational attainment (middle-educated workers) and (iii) at least an undergraduate degree (high-educated workers). The share of low-educated workers serves as reference category.

GMM-SYS estimates are reported in columns (1) to (3). Footnote 23 To examine their reliability, we first apply the Hansen and Arellano-Bond tests. For all regressions, they do not reject respectively the null hypotheses of valid instruments Footnote 24 and of no second order auto-correlation in the first differenced errors. Footnote 25 Results in column (1) indicate that middle- and high-educated workers are significantly more productive than low-educated workers. They also show Footnote 26 that the productivity of middle-educated workers is significantly smaller than that of high-educated workers. The regression coefficient associated with the share of middle-educated workers is equal to 0.106. This means that if the fraction of middle-educated workers within a firm increases by 10 percentage points (and is compensated by a proportional decrease in the share of low-educated workers), mean hourly productivity rises on average by 1.06% (i.e. 0.106 × 0.10 = 0.0106 = 1.06%). Similarly, estimates suggest that increasing the share of high-educated workers by 10 percentage points at the expense of low-educated (middle-educated) workers increases firm hourly productivity on average by 2.58% (1.52%). LP results, reported in column (4), confirm that workers’ educational attainment has a significant positive influence on firm-level productivity. Estimates indeed suggest that hourly value added rises on average by respectively 1.28 and 0.19% following a 10 percentage point increase in the incidence of high- and middle-educated workers (at the expense of the reference educational group). They also indicate that productivity grows on average by 1.09% if the share of high-educated workers increases by 10 percentage points and is compensated by a proportional decrease in the fraction of middle-educated workers.

Turning to the relationship between education and wage costs, results show (see column (2)) that a 10 percentage points rise in the share of middle-educated (high-educated) workers, at the expense of low-educated workers, increases mean hourly wage costs on average by 0.27% (1.45%). Moreover, they suggest that wage costs rise on average by 1.18% if the share of high-educated workers is increased by 10 percentage points and compensated by a comparable decrease in the incidence of middle-educated workers. Findings thus support the existence of a significant upward-sloping relation between education and wage costs.

In order to determine whether marginal wage costs of different educational groups are in line with corresponding output elasticities, we re-estimated our benchmark equation using as dependent variable the value added-wage cost gap. Results, reported in column (3) of Table  2 , suggest that firm rents increase when low-educated workers are substituted by high-educated ones. Indeed, estimates show that the productivity-pay gap rises on average by 0.55% following a 10 percentage point increase in the share of high-educated workers (at the expense of low-educated ones). The additional value generated by high-educated workers relative to their low-educated co-workers is thus found to exceed their wage cost differential. In sum, findings in column (3) suggest that high-educated workers are under-paid relative to their low-educated counterparts (and vice versa). Footnote 27 , Footnote 28 , Footnote 29

To fine-tune our understanding of the education-productivity-pay nexus, we re-estimated our benchmark specification using seven rather than three educational categories. Footnote 30 While the inclusion of additional educational variables is likely to increase the standard errors of our estimates (as the share of observations within each educational group decreases), results reported in Appendix 4 actually support and refine our conclusions. Indeed, they show a significant upward-sloping profile between education and wage costs, on the one hand, and education and productivity, on the other. They also indicate (see estimates in columns (3)) that low-educated workers tend to be over-paid relative to other educational groups. Decreasing their share at the benefit of more educated groups of employees appears indeed to be beneficial for firms’ productivity-wage gaps. Findings thus corroborate the hypothesis that the distribution of wage costs across educational groups is more compressed than the education-productivity profile. More precisely, they support the existence of a ‘wage-compression effect’ according to which the substitution of low- by high-educated workers increases employer rents (and vice versa). Footnote 31

4.2 Estimates across groups of workers

Various theoretical arguments suggest that the education-productivity-pay nexus may depend on workers’ age and gender. As an example, it could be noted that labour market regulations (such as minimum wages or unemployment benefits) essentially affect the lower end of the earnings distribution. As a result, these regulations are more likely to lead to a ‘wage-compression effect’ among workers earning lower wages, e.g. young and female workers (Cardoso 2010 ). Given the importance of this issue and the lack of empirical results, this section examines these interaction effects in more detail.

4.2.1 Does workers’ age matter?

We first focus on the potential impact of workers’ age. To do so, we re-estimated Eqs. (1) to (3), including the education and age share variables in interaction. More precisely, we computed shares of hours worked respectively by young and older workers of different educational groups within firms and estimated their effects on productivity, wage costs and productivity-wage gaps. In order to guarantee that the number of observations in each education-age group was sufficiently large (i.e. to maximise the robustness of our estimates), we fixed the threshold separating young from older workers at 40 years. Footnote 32 Next, following our baseline specification, we split young and older workers in three educational groups. We thus differentiated workers according to whether they were (i) low-educated (i.e. had at most lower secondary education), (ii) middle-educated (i.e. had upper secondary educational attainment), or (iii) high-educated (i.e. had at least an undergraduate degree). The share of young low-educated workers has been used as reference category.

Results are reported in Table  3 . GMM-SYS and LP estimates show (on the basis of chi-squared statistics testing for the equality of regressions coefficients) that older workers’ educational level has a significantly positive impact wage costs and productivity. Footnote 33 They also suggest that education-driven productivity gains among older workers are in line with wage cost differentials. Indeed, older workers’ educational level is not found to affect the productivity-pay gap. Estimates among young workers are somewhat different. On the one hand, they confirm the existence of a positive impact of educational credentials on wage costs and value added. More precisely, they show that young high-educated workers are more productive and costly than young low- and middle-educated workers. On the other hand, they highlight that educational credentials among young workers have a stronger impact on productivity than on wage costs. Results indicate that firms’ rents (measured through the value-added/wage cost gap) rise when young low-educated workers are replaced by young high-educated workers (and vice versa).

As a sensitivity test, we re-estimated our model using four rather than three educational categories and kept the threshold to separate young from older workers at 40 years. Regression results, reported in Appendix 7 , support previous findings according to which education increases productivity and wage costs both among young and older workers. They also suggest that the under-payment (over-payment) of high-educated (low-educated) workers disappears among older cohorts of employees (see column (3)). In sum, it appears that the existence of a ‘wage-compression effect’ is essentially verified among young workers. For older workers, estimates indicate that the distribution of wage costs across educational groups is well aligned with workers’ educational productivity profile.

4.2.2 Does workers’ gender matter?

In order to examine whether the education-productivity-pay nexus depends on workers’ gender, we re-estimated Eqs. (5) to (7), including shares of hours worked respectively by female and male workers with different educational attainments within firms. In line with our baseline specification, we first focused on low-, middle- and high-educated workers. GMM-SYS and LP estimates, reported in Table  4 , show that women’s and men’s education exerts a significantly positive impact on wage costs and productivity. Yet, the relationship between education and wage costs is found to be quite weak for women and definitely weaker than for men. For male workers, we also find that education-driven productivity gains do not deviate significantly from wage cost differentials (see column (3)). In contrast, it appears that productivity is more sensitive to women’s level of education than wage costs. More precisely, results show that firms boost their rents (i.e. their value-added wage cost gap) if they substitute low- or middle-educated female workers by high-educated ones. Tertiary educated women are thus found to be underpaid relative to their same-gender co-workers that are less educated (and vice versa). No such discrepancy is found among male workers.

As a robustness test, we re-estimated our model considering a larger number of educational categories (four instead of three) in interaction with workers’ gender. Results, reported in Appendix 8 , still support the hypothesis that high-educated workers, be they women or men, are more productive and costly than their same-gender lower educated co-workers. As regards potential discrepancies, chi-squared statistics for equality of regression coefficients again suggest that firm-level rents increase significantly when replacing low-educated female workers by more educated ones. They also confirm that no such misalignment is observed for the group of male workers. Footnote 34 , Footnote 35

5 Conclusions

This paper estimates the impact of education on hourly productivity, wage costs and the gap between these two variables at the firm level. It significantly contributes to the existing literature as it is one of the first to (1) use a large representative data set (i.e. Belgian linked employer-employee panel data covering most private-sector firms over the period 1999–2010), (2) address important methodological issues such as firm-level fixed effects, endogeneity and state dependence of firm productivity and wages and (3) examine whether education increases productivity and wage costs equally (i.e. to extend the analysis to wage costs and productivity-wage gaps). It also adds to previous research by providing first evidence on whether the alignment between productivity and wage costs across educational levels depends on workers’ characteristics, i.e. their age and gender.

Findings, based on the generalised method of moments (GMM) and the Levinsohn and Petrin ( 2003 ) estimator, show a robust upward-sloping profile between education and wage costs, on the one hand, and education and productivity, on the other. They also systematically highlight that educational credentials have a stronger impact on productivity than on wage costs. Firms’ profitability (i.e. productivity-wage gap) is indeed found to rise when lower educated workers are substituted by higher educated ones (and vice versa). Estimates thus support the existence of a ‘wage-compression effect’, i.e. a situation in which the distribution of wage costs is more compressed than workers’ education-productivity profile. More precisely, they suggest that firm rents increase on average by 1.4% (0.6%) in the long run (short run) if the fraction of high-educated workers within a firm increases by 10 percentage points (and is compensated by a proportional decrease in the share of low-educated workers). Yet, the size of this effect is found to depend crucially on workers’ characteristics (i.e. their age and gender). The misalignment between education-driven productivity gains and wage cost differentials appears to be only verified among young workers. Put differently, results suggest that high-educated (low-educated) workers are no longer under-paid (over-paid) when they become older. Findings are also quite different according to gender. Results show that the level of education of women has a significantly stronger positive effect on their productivity than on their wage costs. Highly educated women are thus found to be under-paid relative to their same-gender co-workers who are less educated (and vice versa). In contrast, for male workers, education-driven productivity gains are not found to deviate significantly from wage cost differentials.

How can these findings be interpreted? Results from our baseline specification showing the existence of a ‘wage-compression effect’ partially back up the predictions of human capital theory. On the one hand, they corroborate the idea that education develops skills that make workers more productive and that wages reflect differences in productivity. On the other, they do not support the hypothesis that education-driven productivity gains are well aligned with wage differentials. Our findings are also not in line with theories (based on tournaments, internal decision-making processes of organisations or monitoring issues) Footnote 36 , Footnote 37 suggesting that high-educated workers are overpaid relative to their respective output elasticities. Estimates are actually more compatible with the literature on social norms and the hysteresis of the wage structure, Footnote 38 fairness theories Footnote 39 and especially arguments according to which labour market regulations—such as minimum wages, collective bargaining and unemployment benefits—increase the reservation wage, especially for workers at the bottom of the wage distribution, and reduce wage inequalities by pushing earnings of low-wage workers upwards (Cahuc and Zylberberg 2014 ).

Results according to workers’ age can be understood through additional hypothesis testing. Estimates, based on our benchmark regression (see Table  3 ), suggest that the education-driven wage cost differential is smaller among young workers than among older workers (z-statistic = −2.48 and p value = 0.01), while the contribution of education to firm’s value added is not found to be statistically different across age groups (z-statistics = −0.58 and p value = 0.56). Footnote 40 , Footnote 41 The observation that the wage cost differential between high- and low-educated workers increases with workers’ age can be explained by the fact that white-collar workers in Belgium are much more likely to be paid according to seniority than their blue-collar counterparts (which are typically less educated); this is arguably a result of separate collective agreements for blue- and white-collar workers and more widespread use of seniority-related pay scales in the agreements covering the latter (for more details see, e.g. Kampelmann and Rycx 2013 ). As a result, seniority-pay profiles are generally much steeper for high- than low-educated workers. A complementary explanation is that labour market regulations essentially affect the lower end of the wage distribution. Hence, they are more likely to compress the wage cost differential between low- and high-educated workers when they are young. Footnote 42 Overall, results thus suggest that high-educated (low-educated) workers are no longer under-paid (over-paid) when they become older because their wage cost to productivity ratio increases at a faster (slower) pace during their career than that of low-educated (high-educated) workers. Footnote 43

Estimates by gender suggest that the over-payment (under-payment) of low-educated (high-educated) workers only holds for women. This finding may be explained by the fact that women are over-represented among low-wage earners and are thus more likely to have their working conditions influenced by labour market regulations. However, the stronger wage-compression effect among women might also result from discrimination and the existence of a glass-ceiling effect, i.e. the fact that women face invisible but real barriers preventing them from obtaining higher-level positions. Indeed, results of Kampelmann and Rycx ( 2012 ) show that the occupation-pay profile in Belgian is steeper than the occupation-productivity profile. Accordingly, the fact that women are less likely to hold jobs at the upper rungs of the corporate ladder should ceteris paribus have a stronger detrimental effect on their pay than on their productivity.

Our finding that high-educated women are underpaid could thus be explained by the fact that education raises women’s productivity but only weakly raises their wages since a glass ceiling is stopping them from reaching top positions. A complementary argument, provided by Card et al. ( 2016 : 1), is that high-educated women, in a given occupation, ‘are less likely to initiate wage bargaining with their employer and are (often) less effective negotiators than men’. These interpretations echo the estimates of Garnero et al. ( 2014 ). The latter show that women generate employer rents in the Belgian private sector and that these rents derive from the fact that women earn less than men at any given level of productivity, i.e. are discriminated against.

To sum up, our results show that firms located in Belgium face financial disincentives to employ low-educated workers, especially when they are young. We indeed find that firms employing a larger share of young low-educated workers tend to be less profitable. Policies aiming to improve the labour market prospects of young low-educated workers should thus try to boost their productivity and/or to decrease their wage cost. A substantial number of policies (i.e. training programmes, wage subsidies, reductions of social security contributions) are already implemented in Belgium to reach this goal. Yet, our findings suggest that these efforts should be continued and intensified (alongside policies fostering total employment). Furthermore, results show that the wage-compression effect only holds for women. This finding suggests that particular attention should be devoted to the productivity to wage cost ratio of low-educated women but also to policies favouring gender equality in terms of remuneration and career advancement.

At the macro level, some studies suggest that education fosters output per worker and income per capita (Krueger and Lindahl 2001 ). However, the use of cross-country panel data over long periods makes the identification of the causal relationship between education and productivity difficult. In particular, controlling for reverse causality (i.e. for the fact that countries with higher growth rates invest more in education) remains challenging (Sianesi and Van Reenen 2003 ).

Much more effort has actually been devoted to understand the productivity consequences of other workforce characteristics such as age, gender, part-time or temporary contracts (see e.g. Cardoso et al. 2011 ; Garnero et al. 2014 ; Giuliano et al. 2017 ; Devicienti et al. 2017 ; Göbel and Zwick 2012 ; Hellerstein et al. 1999a ; Nielen and Schiersch 2014 ; van Ours and Stoeldraijer 2011 ).

For a detailed description of how some of the prominent theories on mismatches between productivity and wages can be adapted to account for workers’ educational heterogeneity, see Rycx et al. ( 2015 ).

We also show results of a more structural approach suggested by Levinsohn and Petrin ( 2003 ). For more details, see section 2.3.

Figures for the OECD area show a very similar pattern (OECD 2015 ). For example, the unemployment rate among the low-educated is more than two times bigger than among tertiary educated workers (i.e. 13.5 and 5.3% in 2013). Moreover, the employment rate is almost 30 percentage points higher among tertiary educated people than among low-educated ones (i.e. 83.1 and 54.9% in 2013).

For evidence on workforce over-education/qualification, see e.g. McGuinness ( 2006 ) or Montt ( 2017 ).

This is estimated through the ‘perpetual inventory method’ (or PIM, see e.g. OECD ( 2009 ) for more details). The PIM incorporates the idea that the capital stock results from investment flows and corrects for capital depreciation and efficiency losses. Following standard practice, we assume a 5% annual rate of depreciation.

This variable indicates whether wages in the firm are collectively negotiated at the firm level (in addition to national and/or sectoral collective wage agreements that are the norm in Belgium).

All independent variables are measured in terms of shares in total work hours. For instance, the fraction of part-time workers is computed on the basis of the proportion of hours worked by employees working less than 30 h per week over the total amount of hours worked with the firm. The control variables that have been included in our regressions are in line with the existing literature (for a review of the set of covariates that should be included in this type of analysis see e.g. Göbel and Zwick 2012 ). As highlighted by Mahlberg et al. ( 2013 : 10): ‘by including a rather broad set of independent variables, we account for heterogeneity among firms, in order to mitigate the bias that could be caused by omitted variables’.

Expected biases associated with OLS and the relatively poor performance and shortcomings of the FE estimator in the context of firm-level productivity regressions are reviewed in Van Beveren ( 2012 ).

We have performed such a test by using a 2SLS estimator on an equation in levels in which our variables of interest are instrumented by first differences. All three equations (i.e. value added, wage costs and gap) pass standard underidentification and weak identification tests. This means that the endogeneity test for the educational variables is valid. This test suggests that for all three equations we have to reject the null hypothesis that educational variables can actually be treated as exogenous

By ‘educational variables’, we mean shares of workers by educational level and other input factors.

Bond and Söderbom ( 2005 ) provide a review of the literature regarding the identification of production functions. The authors notably highlight that adjustment costs of labour and capital can justify the use of lagged values (of endogenous variables) as instruments.

In the case of our data, the lags we used in the estimator do not correspond exactly to a yearly lag; this is due to the fact that the dependent variables are measured in year t whereas the independent variables are measured in October of year t  − 1. See the presentation of data in Section 3 .

Yet, as a robustness test, we also estimated Eqs. (1) to (3) with a static GMM-SYS estimator. Our main findings remain unaffected using this alternative estimator (see Appendix 5 ).

It thus covers the following sectors: (i) mining and quarrying (C), (ii) manufacturing (D), (iii) electricity, gas and water supply (E), (iv) construction (F), (v) wholesale and retail trade, repair of motor vehicles, motorcycles and personal and household goods (G), (vi) hotels and restaurants (H), (vii) transport, storage and communication (I), (viii) financial intermediation (J), and ix) real estate, renting and business activities (K).

The SES is a stratified sample. For details on stratification criteria see Appendix 10 .

For instance, we eliminate a (very small) number of firms for which the recorded value added was negative.

This restriction is unlikely to affect our results as it leads to a very small drop in sample size. The average number of observations per firm in each year is equal to 37 in our final sample.

All variables measured in monetary terms have been deflated to constant prices of 2004 by the consumer price index taken from Statistics Belgium.

OLS estimates (using respectively 3 and 7 educational categories) are reported in Appendices 1 and 2 .

As noted in Section 2.1 , this variable is measured by the value added-wage cost gap, i.e. the difference between log hourly value added and log hourly wage costs.

Note that lagged dependent variables are always found to be highly significant in our regressions. In line with the existing literature (see Section 2.1 ), they confirm that productivity, wage costs and profitability are highly persistent at the firm level. Moreover, GMM coefficients on lagged dependent variables fall systematically between the OLS and FE estimates (available on request). As highlighted by Roodman ( 2009 ), this result supports the appropriateness of our dynamic GMM-SYS specification.

First and second lags of explanatory variables (except time dummies) are used as instruments.

We also tested for weak instruments by computing the Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic (van Ours and Stoeldraijer 2011 ). Given that this test is not applicable in a GMM-SYS specification, we used a GMM specification in first differences in which the first-differenced shares of education variables were instrumented by their lagged levels (in t  − 1 and t  − 2). We reject the null hypothesis of weak instruments for all models presented in this paper, including the models that differentiate education groups by age and gender.

On the basis of a chi-squared test for equality of regression coefficients.

The exclusion of firm size among covariates does not affect our conclusions (results available on request).

Note that regression coefficients obtained through a dynamic specification correspond to short-run effects. To obtain the long-run impact of changes in educational shares on productivity, wage costs and profits, Koyck ( 1954 ) has shown that estimates reported in Table  2 should be divided by 1 minus the coefficient associated to the lagged dependent variable. Applying this transformation to our benchmark results, we find that elasticities are approximately two times bigger in the long run than in the short run.

As a robustness test, we re-estimated our benchmark model (i.e. Eqs. (1) to (3)) adding among explanatory variables: (a) the squared values of capital and educational variables, (b) the cross-product between capital and educational variables, (c) the cross-product between educational variables. Put differently, we adopted a translog specification. Estimates, reported in Appendix 3 , confirm that education has a positive impact on productivity and on wage costs (see columns (1) and (2)). However, the inclusion of interaction terms and squared values of capital and educational variables increases the standard errors of our estimates. Yet, they remain qualitatively similar to those obtained with our benchmark specification (see Table 2 ). Estimates using the productivity-wage gap as dependent variable are reported in column (3). They confirm that firm rents (i.e. productivity-wage gaps) increase significantly when low-educated workers are substituted by high-educated ones. Indeed, estimates show that the productivity-pay gap rises on average by 1.5% following a 10 percentage point increase in the share of high-educated workers (at the expense of lower educated ones).

We differentiated workers according to whether they had (i) at most primary education, (ii) lower or upper secondary education, (iii) a Bachelor’s or equivalent degree and (iv) at least a Master’s or equivalent degree. In comparison to our benchmark model, this specification focuses on very low-educated workers and distinguishes between workers with first- and advanced-level tertiary education.

Note that results (see Appendix 5 ) based on a static GMM-SYS estimator leave our conclusions unaffected. Yet, as expected (see footnote 28), the size of regression coefficients is found to be larger than in dynamic specifications.

As can be seen from columns (1) to (3) of Appendix 6 , this age limit generates a quite balanced distribution of observations across education-age groups. Nevertheless, we also tested the robustness of our estimates fixing the threshold at 50 years. Vandenberghe et al. ( 2013 ) indeed suggest that the pay-productivity gap is reversed at a higher age (which they identify at 56). Results based on the 50 years threshold (available on request) corroborate our conclusions .

The positive relationship between older workers’ educational attainment and firm productivity is only significant at the 12% probability level in the GMM-SYS specification.

Note that men and women have approximately the same age in our sample (respectively, 39.5 and 37.6 years with a standard deviation equal to 10.4 and 10.1). The fact that our results are significantly more pronounced for women than for men does hence not appear to derive from differences in the latter’s age.

We also re-estimated our benchmark equations separately for firms operating respectively in the industry and services. Results (reported in Rycx et al. 2015 ) corroborate findings for the overall sample of firms. Indeed, for both sectors, they highlight that (a) workers’ educational credentials raise productivity and wage costs and (b) high-educated workers are underpaid (i.e. increase firm profits) with respect to their low-educated counterparts.

Tournament theory predicts a convex relationship between a worker’s pay and his position in the firm’s hierarchy, to the extent that workers at the top of the hierarchy receive wages beyond their marginal products. Given that low-educated workers are generally found at the bottom of corporate hierarchies, this theory suggests that firm-level profits should increase with the share of low-educated workers (Lazear and Rosen 1981 ).

The theory put forward by Osterman et al. ( 2009 : 705) suggests that any rent generated by the firm is unequally distributed among educational groups. Moreover, the analysis of principal-agent problems suggests that wages of higher educated workers might be higher than predicted by standard competitive theory (Bebchuk and Fried 2003 ).

Given that technological change over the past decades appears to be skill/task biased and that low-educated workers are typically less skilled and often doing more routine tasks (Goos et al. 2014 ), the hysteresis in social norms discussed by Doeringer and Piore ( 1985 ) and Skott ( 2005 ) could lead to the overpayment of low-educated workers whose productivity might have been negatively affected by technological change, and the underpayment of high-educated workers whose productivity might have increased.

Following Hamermesh ( 1975 ) and Akerlof and Yellen ( 1988 ), there is an efficiency argument in paying high-productivity jobs in a firm below and low-productivity jobs above their marginal products so as to compress the overall wage structure.

These results are obtained with the ‘lincom’ command in STATA, after estimating the same regressions as in Table  4 but using as reference category ‘young middle-educated workers’ (i.e. YE34). The exact syntax is as follows: lincom YE567 – YE12 – OE567 + OE12.

We do not reject the hypothesis that the education-driven productivity differential may decrease among older cohorts of workers, notably among 50+ workers. Yet, it is difficult to provide consistent evidence on this as the number of observations within each education-age group decreases quite substantially when moving the age threshold from 40 to 50 years.

It should, however, be borne in mind that ‘education’ is not perfectly constant over time since the different age groups in our sample obtained their educational credentials at different moments in time. These credentials could therefore reflect different types of skills across generations that attended school at different moments in time (for a more complete discussion of the underlying issue, see e.g. Cataldi et al. ( 2011 )).

Our estimates are also compatible with the employer learning literature (see e.g. Altonji and Pierret 2001 ). The intuition is as follows: as workers become older there is more and more information available to assess their true productivity and hence it becomes easier to set wages that align well with their productivity.

Akerlof G, Yellen J (1988) Fairness and unemployment. Am Econ Rev 78:44–49

Google Scholar  

Altonji J, Pierret C (2001) Employer learning and statistical discrimination. Q J Econ 116:313–350

Article   Google Scholar  

Arellano M, Bond O (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-component models. J Econ 68:28–51

Bartolucci C (2013) Gender wage gaps reconsidered a structural approach using matched employer-employee data. J Hum Resour 48(4):998–1034

Bebchuk L, Fried J (2003) Executive compensation as an agency problem. J Econ Perspect 17:71–92

Becker G (1964) Human capital. NBER, New York

Belgian federal government 2015. National plan programme 2015, Brussels

Berg I (1981) Sociological perspectives on labor markets. London: Academic Press

Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econ 87:115–143

Bond S (2002) Dynamic panel data models: a guide to micro data methods and practice. Port Econ J 1:141–162

Bond, S., and Söderbom, M. 2005. ‘Adjustment costs and the identification of Cobb Douglas production functions.’ IFS Working Paper, No. 05/04, London

Bou J, Satorra A (2007) The persistence of abnormal returns at industry and firm levels: evidence from Spain. Strateg Manag J 28:707–722

Cahuc P, Carcillo S (2012) Les conséquences des allègements généraux de cotisations patronales sur les bas salaires. Revue Française d’économie 27:19–61

Cahuc P, Zylberberg A (2014) Labor economics. MIT Press, Cambridge

Card D, Cardoso A, Kline P (2016) Bargaining and the gender wage gap: a direct assessment. Q J Econ 131:633–686

Card D, Kluve J, Weber A (2010) Active labour market policy evaluations: a meta-analysis. Econ J 120:F452–F477

Cardoso A (2010) Do firms compress the wage distribution. In: Marsden D (ed) Wage structures, employment adjustments and globalisation: evidence from linked and firm-level panel data, Palgrave Macmillan, pp 202–218

Cardoso A, Guimaraes P, Varejao J (2011) Are older workers worthy of their pay? An empirical investigation of age-productivity and age-wage nexuses. De Economist 159:95–111

Cataldi A, Kampelmann S, Rycx F (2011) Productivity-wage gaps among age groups: does the ICT environment matter? De Economist 159(2):193–221

Cockx, B., and Dejemeppe, M. 2002. ‘Do the higher educated unemployed crowd out the lower educated ones in competition for jobs?’, IZA Discussion Paper, No. 541, Bonn

Demunter C (2000) Structure and dispersion of earnings survey. Working Paper, Statistics Belgium, Brussels

Devicienti, F., Grinza, E. and Vannoni, D. 2017. ‘The impact of part-time work on firm total factor productivity: evidence from Italy.’ Industrial and Corporate Change, forthcoming

Doeringer P, Piore M. (1985) Internal labor markets and manpower analysis. ME Sharpe, Armonk.

Dolado J, Felgueroso F, Jimeno J (2000) Youth labour markets in Spain: education, training crowding out. Eur Econ Rev 44:943–956

Eurostat (2016a) Labour force survey. Eurostat, Luxemburg

Eurostat (2016b) Labour market policy – expenditure and participants – data 2013. Eurostat, Luxembourg

Fuss, C., and Wintr, L. 2009. ‘Rigid labour compensation and flexible employment? Firm-level evidence with regard to productivity for Belgium’, ECB Working Paper, No. 1021, Frankfurt

Galindo-Rueda, F., and Haskel, J. 2005. ‘Skills, workforce characteristics and firm-level productivity: evidence from the matched ABI/employer skills survey’, IZA Discussion Paper, No. 1542, Bonn

Garnero A, Kampelmann S, Rycx F (2014) Part-time work, wages and productivity: evidence from Belgian matched panel data. Ind Labor Relat Rev 67:926–954

Gautier P, van den Berg G, van Ours J, Ridder G (2002) Worker turnover at the firm level and crowding out of lower educated workers. Eur Econ Rev 46:523–538

Giuliano R, Kampelmann S, Mahy B, Rycx F (2017) Short notice, big difference? The effect of temporary employment on firm competitiveness across sectors. Br J Ind Relat 55:421–449

Göbel C, Zwick T (2012) Age and productivity: sector differences. De Economist 160:35–57

Goos M, Manning A, Salomons A (2014) Explaining job polarization: routine-biased technological change and offshoring. Am Econ Rev 104:2509–2526

Haegeland T, Klette T (1999) Do higher wages reflect higher productivity? Education, gender and experience premiums in a matched plant-worker data set. In: Haltiwanger J, Lane J, Spletzer J, Theeuwes J, Troske K (eds) The creation and analysis of employer-employee matched data. Elsevier, North-Holland, pp 231–259

Chapter   Google Scholar  

Haltiwanger J, Lane J, Spetze J (1999) Productivity differences across employers: the roles of employer size, age and human capital. Am Econ Rev 89:94–98

Hamermesh D (1975) Interdependence in the labour market. Economica 42:420–429

Hansen L (1982) Large sample properties of generalized method of moment estimators. Econometrica 50:1029–1054

Heckman J, LaLonde R, Smith J (1999) The economics and econometrics of active labor market programs. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1865–2097

Hellerstein, J., and Neumark, D. 2004. ‘Production function and wage equation estimation with heterogeneous labor: evidence from a new matched employer-employee data set’, NBER Working Paper, No. 10365, Cambridge (Ma.)

Book   Google Scholar  

Hellerstein J, Neumark D, Troske K (1999a) Sex, wages, productivity: an empirical analysis of Israel firm-level data. Int Econ Rev 40:95–123

Hellerstein J, Neumark D, Troske K (1999b) Wages, productivity and worker characteristics: evidence from plant-level production functions and wage equations. J Labor Econ 17:409–446

Hempell T. (2005) What's spurious? What's real? Measuring the productivity impacts of ICT at the firm level. Empir Econ 30:427–464.

Ilmakunnas P, Maliranta M (2005) Technology, labour characteristics and wage-productivity gaps. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 67:623–645

Kalleberg A, Sørensen A (1979) The sociology of labor markets. Annu Rev Sociol 5:351–379

Kampelmann S, Rycx F (2012) Are occupations paid what they are worth? An econometric study of occupational wage inequality and productivity. De Economist 160:257–287

Kampelmann S, Rycx F (2013) Does institutional diversity account for pay rules in Germany and Belgium? Soc Econ Rev 11:131–157 2013

Kluve J (2010) The effectiveness of European active labor market programs. Labour Econ 17:904–918

Koyck L (1954) Distributed lags and investment analysis. Amsterdam: North Holland

Krueger A, Lindahl M (2001) Education and growth: why and for whom? J Econ Lit 39:1101–1136

Lazear E, Rosen S (1981) Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. J Polit Econ 89:841–864

Lazear E, Shaw K (2007) Personnel economics: the economist’s view of human resources. J Econ Perspect 21:91–114

Levinsohn J, Petrin A (2003) Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud 70:317–341

Mahlberg B, Freund I, Cuaresma J, Prskawets A (2013) Ageing productivity and wages in Austria. Labour Econ 22:5–15

McGuinness S (2006) Overeducation in the labour market. J Econ Surv 20:238–418

Montt G (2017) Field-of-study mismatch and overqualification: labour market correlates and their wage penalty. IZA J Labor Econ 6:2

Moretti E (2004) Workers’ education, spillovers and productivity: evidence from plant-level production functions. Am Econ Rev 94:656–690

Nielen S, Schiersch A (2014) Temporary agency work and firm competitiveness: evidence from German manufacturing firms. Ind Relat 53:365–393

OECD (2009) Measuring capital. OECD, Paris

OECD (2015) OECD employment outlook 2015. OECD, Paris

Osterman P, Auer P, Gautié J, Marsden D (2009) Discussion: a new labour economics? Soc Econ Rev 7:695–726

Roodman D (2009) How to do xtabond2: an introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. Stata J 9:86–136

Rycx, F., Saks, Y., and Tojerow, I. 2015. ‘Does education raise productivity and wages equally? The moderating roles of age, gender and industry’, IZA Discussion Paper, No. 9043, Bonn

Sianesi B, Van Reenen J (2003) The returns to education: macroeconomics. J Econ Surv 17:157–200

Skott P (2005) Fairness as a source of hysteresis in employment and relative wages. J Econ Behav Organ 57:305–331

Syverson C (2011) What determines productivity? J Econ Lit 49:326–365

Van Beveren I (2012) Total factor productivity estimation: a practical review. J Econ Surv 26:98–128

Van Biesebroeck J (2011) Wages equal productivity. Fact or fiction? Evidence from sub-Saharan Africa. World Econ 39:1333–1346

van Ours J, Stoeldraijer L (2011) Age, wage and productivity in Dutch manufacturing. De Economist 159:113–137

Vandenberghe V, Waltenberg F, Rigo M (2013) Ageing and employability. Evidence from Belgian firm-level data. J Prod Anal 40:111–136

Weeden K (2002) Why do some occupations pay more than others? Social closure and earnings inequality in the United States. Am J Sociol 108:55–101

Wooldridge J (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT Press, Cambridge (Ma.)

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the National Bank of Belgium (NBB) for financial support and to Statistics Belgium (DGSIE) for giving access to the data. We also would like to thank Philippe Delhez, Francesco Devicienti, Catherine Fuss, Maarten Goos, Wolter Hassink, Sile O’Dorchai, Raul Ramos, Bruno Van der Linden, Vincent Vandenberghe, Dieter Verhaest, Raf Wouters and participants at various conferences and seminars (notably at the University of Barcelona and Utrecht and at the  SOLE, EALE, LEER, NBB, IWEPS, Meet2Know, Skill Mismatch and USE conferences) for very helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper. We would also like to thank the anonymous referees and the editor for the helpful remarks. The views expressed here are our own and do not necessarily reflect those of the NBB. None of the authors have any competing interests in the manuscript.

Responsible editor: Pierre Cahuc.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Université libre de Bruxelles, SBS-EM, CEB and DULBEA, Avenue F. Roosevelt, 50, B-1050, Brussels, Belgium

Stephan Kampelmann, François Rycx & Ilan Tojerow

National Bank of Belgium, Boulevard du Berlaimont, 14, B-1000, Brussels, Belgium

IZA, Bonn, Germany

François Rycx & Ilan Tojerow

IRES, Louvain-la Neuve, Belgium

François Rycx

humanOrg, Mons, Belgium

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to François Rycx .

Ethics declarations

Competing interests.

The IZA Journal of Labor Economics is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The authors declare that they have observed these principles.

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix 10

1.1 stratification criteria of the ses.

The stratification criteria used in the SES refer respectively to the region (NUTS groups), the principal economic activity (NACE groups) and the size of the firm. The sample size in each stratum depends on the size of the firm. Sampling percentages of firms are respectively equal to 10, 50 and 100% when the number of workers is lower than 50, between 50 and 99, and above 100. Within a firm, sampling percentages of employees also depend on size. Sampling percentages of employees reach respectively 100, 50, 25, 14.3 and 10% when the number of workers is lower than 20, between 20 and 50, between 50 and 99, between 100 and 199, and between 200 and 299. Firms employing 300 workers or more have to report information for an absolute number of employees. This number ranges between 30 (for firms with between 300 and 349 workers) and 200 (for firms with 12,000 workers or more). To guarantee that firms report information on a representative sample of their workers, they are asked to follow a specific procedure. First, they have to rank their employees in alphabetical order. Next, Statistics Belgium gives them a random letter (e.g. the letter O) from which they have to start when reporting information on their employees (following the alphabetical order of workers’ names in their list). If they reach the letter Z and still have to provide information on some of their employees, they have to continue from the letter A in their list. Moreover, firms that employ different categories of workers, namely managers, blue- and/or white-collar workers, have to set up a separate alphabetical list for each of these categories and to report information on a number of workers in these different groups that is proportional to their share in the firm’s total employment. For example, a firm with 300 employees (namely, 60 managers, 180 white-collar workers and 60 blue-collar workers) will have to report information on 30 workers (namely, 6 managers, 18 white-collar workers and 6 blue-collar workers). For more details see Demunter ( 2000 ).

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License ( http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ ), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Kampelmann, S., Rycx, F., Saks, Y. et al. Does education raise productivity and wages equally? The moderating role of age and gender. IZA J Labor Econ 7 , 1 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40172-017-0061-4

Download citation

Received : 03 February 2017

Accepted : 18 December 2017

Published : 23 January 2018

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1186/s40172-017-0061-4

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

JEL Classification

  • Labour costs
  • Productivity
  • Age Linked panel data

economics case studies wages and education

  • Corpus ID: 154477587

The Effect of Education and Experience on Wages: The Case Study of Thailand in 2012

  • Wit Wannakrairoj
  • Published 2013
  • Economics, Education

Tables from this paper

table 1

14 Citations

Does education and experience matter in the distribution of wages in nepal a quantile regression approach, the effect of educational attainment and work experiences on earnings in indonesian manufacturing sectors.

  • Highly Influenced

The Effect of Education and Experience on Wages: The Case Study of Saudi Arabia

The economic significance of work experience for elderly employment in thailand, nexus between educational attainment and income in khulna city: an empirical exploration, the role of cognitive and non-cognitive skills on labour market outcomes in indonesia, return to education in azerbaijan. does gender matter, reducing spatial inequality in indonesia: off-the-job training as a special treatment for underdeveloped regions, pooled ols and fixed effect estimation of wage structure and differential in handloom sector: choosing the better method, is living standard in urban areas better than rural areas evidence from educational factor in indonesia., 25 references, higher education and the starting wages of graduates in china, private sector training and its impact on the earnings of young workers, unequal access to education and income distribution, decomposing the education wage gap: everything but the kitchen sink, human capital, income inequality and kuznets' hypothesis in thailand, does education reduce wage inequality quantile regression evidence from 16 countries, human capital, technology, and the wage structure: what do time series show, the polish wage inequality explosion, training and the growth of wage inequality, related papers.

Showing 1 through 3 of 0 Related Papers

The Impact of Overeducation on Wages of Recent Economic Sciences Graduates

  • Original Research
  • Published: 05 March 2022
  • Volume 163 , pages 409–445, ( 2022 )

Cite this article

economics case studies wages and education

  • Mariana Olga De Santis   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0003-2953-9141 1 , 2 ,
  • María Cecilia Gáname 1 , 2 &
  • Pedro Esteban Moncarz   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-6023-6619 1 , 2 , 3  

628 Accesses

Explore all metrics

According to human capital theory, wages are determined by workers' productivity which, in its crudest form, implies that return to education does not depend on how workers' skills are used. However, after controlling for other differences, the empirical evidence shows that workers with identical education are paid differently. The literature evidences that young people are more likely to experience a mismatch between their formal education and the one required for their jobs. While there is no consensus on the reasons for the mismatch phenomenon, one consequence is clear, in terms of wages overeducation means a penalty. Our evidence shows that overeducated graduates of the Facultad de Ciencias Económicas of the Universidad Nacional de Córdoba suffer a wage penalty compared to those working in a job that requires a university degree. The results are robust to different specifications and the use of alternative estimators. Even though is not statistically significant, the penalty of a severe level of overeducation is higher than one for a mild level of overeducation; having had work experience while studying at university helps to reduce the cost of overeducation; women exhibit a similar penalty to men. While on average overeducation means a wage penalty, there is great heterogeneity among overeducated graduates, with those at the top end of the wage distribution experiencing a much lower penalty, or even a premium in some cases. Finally, while in the case of overeducation we find statistically significant effects, the same is not true of the horizontal mismatch in terms of knowledge.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price includes VAT (Russian Federation)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Rent this article via DeepDyve

Institutional subscriptions

economics case studies wages and education

Similar content being viewed by others

economics case studies wages and education

Overeducation among Italian graduates: do different measures diverge?

Factors associated with overeducation among recent graduates during labour market integration: the case of catalonia (spain).

economics case studies wages and education

The evolution of educational wage differentials for women and men in Germany, from 1996 to 2019

Data availability.

After an embargo period the data used in this study will be available upon request.

We also worked with an additional variable looking at the degree of match between the skills acquired in university and the required by the job, but it proved to be not significant in the econometric analysis.

Interestingly, in a recent study, Delaney et al. ( 2020 ) look at the relationship between changes in the composition of educational attainment and overeducation rates among new labour market entrants holding post-secondary and tertiary qualifications for 30 European countries over the period 2000–2016, finding that despite the significant increases in the percentage of young people with tertiary level of education, overeducation among new tertiary graduates fell, with some of the greatest declines occurred in the countries experiencing the most significant expansion in tertiary education.

Authors take into account the assignment theory in order to analyse the impact of such phenomena on wages.

Also, workers are asked to answer about the field of education that is most adequate for their jobs by delimiting the responses to these categories: only the own field of education, the own or related field of education, a completely different field of education, for the job there is no specific field required, and for the job there is not exist a specific field yet.

The WA method requires that individuals answer about the full title of their occupation and describe the main tasks and duties in their job.

Amenity/constraint-related reasons comprise those related to family, job location, and working conditions while career-oriented reasons include, for instance, pay and promotion opportunities or a change in career interests.

The FCE is located at the capital of the Province of Córdoba; but an important number of students come from the provinces of Catamarca, La Rioja, Santiago del Estero, Tucumán, Salta and Jujuy. Historically, the UNC has been the destiny of students coming from neighbouring countries, especially Bolivia, Paraguay and Peru. Recently there has been an important influx of students from Brazil and Venezuela.

While the meaning of over/under-education is quite well established in the literature, with their measurement depending on the information available to the researcher, the mismatch in terms of skills is a more elusive concept. In the literature we can find, at least, two approaches. One that looks at the skills in terms of the formal knowledge the person acquired at the school, while the second approach tries to identify the role of innate or acquired abilities. Among the first approach we have the aforementioned works of Allen & van der Velden ( 2001 ), Deželan & Hafner ( 2014 ), Zhu ( 2014 ), and Sellami et al. ( 2017 ), all of whom look at the mismatch between the field of study or the knowledge acquired in school and that required by the job, Deželan & Hafner ( 2014 ) and Sellami et al. ( 2017 ) refer to this mismatch as horizontal. Examples of the second approach are Badillo-Amador & Vila ( 2013 ) and Mavromaras et al. ( 2013 ), both looking at to what extent a person uses in the job his/her personal capabilities and abilities, which are not necessarily derived and/or related to the person's formal education.

Examples of other studies using a self-declared status are Battu et al. ( 1999 ), Dolton & Vignoles ( 2000 ), Ordine & Rose ( 2015 ), and Turmo-Garuz et al. ( 2019 ). Kler ( 2005 ) makes a comparison of the other two definitions using data of Australian university graduates. Capsada-Munsech ( 2019 ) provides evidence on the variation across overeducation measurements using REFLEX/HEGESCO and EULFS datasets. Verhaest & Omey ( 2010 ) analyse the determinants of overeducation among Flemish school leavers in their first job using three alternative ways of measuring overeducation, on the basis of job analysis, self-assessments and realised matches.

Even when it is not possible to make a direct comparison, these figures are within the range found in the literature on the topic.

There were 24 possible intervals, the first one corresponded to those who declared an income of less than A$3000 a month, while the last one represented an income of A$25,000 or more. The remaining intervals were defined using an A$1000 range.

For the lowest interval we use the upper limit of it, while for the highest interval we use its lower limit.

As we are dealing with university graduates, undereducation is not a possible status unless a person declares his/her job requires postgraduate studies. Even when in a very few cases people have declared to be in such situation, we choose to consider them as correctly matched.

Mavromaras et al. ( 2013 ) do not evidence a significant effect of the non-single status on wages. Alternatively, Di Pietro & Urwin ( 2006 ) explore the effects of more family contexts and find, for example, that having a child impacts positively on wages.

Also Dolton & Silles ( 2008 ) evidence that individuals that work in firms of a medium size obtain a higher wage.

Also, we run our different models including other control variables, such as knowledge of foreign language and of software packages, sector of activity, having people economically dependent, average grade at university, and the degree obtained. In all cases we did not find significant estimates, and since its exclusion did not affect the results for the remaining variables here reported, we choose to exclude them with the aim of simplicity and easy of presentation. These results are available upon request.

Gaeta et al. ( 2021 ) propose a heteroscedasticity-based instrumental variable estimation approach to deal with the potential bias from the use of cross-section data. Applying the estimator to a sample of Italian PhD holders, the results show that previous studies provided slightly upward estimates of the impact of vertical mismatch on wages. Alternatively, to deal with the bias arising from the use of cross-section data, Park ( 2021 ) uses a propensity score matching estimator on a sample of Korean doctorate holders.

Di Pietro & Urwin ( 2006 ) point out that according to the assignment theory of overeducation, the concepts of educational and skills mismatch are closely related, as workers report that their educational level is inadequate for the job they occupy due to a poor match between the knowledge and skills acquired during their years of study and those needed to actually perform their job. Thus, when controlling for both phenomena, rather than taking into account only the effect of overeducation, a reduction in the magnitude of the effect associated with overeducation would mean that the assignment theory seems an accurate explanation of the observed wage effects of educational mismatch. In contrast, if educational and skill mismatches reflect different phenomena, controlling for the latter should have little impact on the effect associated with the former.

As pointed out by Zhu ( 2014 ), the method of Li & Racine is appropriate when most explanatory variables are discrete, as it is in our case.

An alternative approach, as in Ordine & Rose ( 2015 ), would be the estimation of a quintile regression model, which would also provide us with different estimates along the wage distribution.

Among the overeducated graduates whose income put them at the fourth quartile, around one third enjoys a wage premium.

More recently, these initiatives have started to take place in some of the largest public universities in Argentina, especially in areas of study related to applied sciences. Within a broader policy of follow-up of its graduates, the FCE-UNC has also started to work on this issue.

Albrecht, J., Edin, P.-A., Sundström, M., & Vroman, S. (1999). Career interruptions and subsequent earnings: A reexamination using Swedish data. Journal of Human Resources, 34 , 294–311.

Article   Google Scholar  

Allen, J., & van der Velden, R. (2001). Educational mismatches versus skill mismatches: Effects on wages, job satisfaction and on-the-job search. Oxford Economic Papers, 53 , 434–452.

Badillo-Amador, L., & Vila, L. (2013). Education and skill mismatches: Wage and job satisfaction consequences. International Journal of Manpower, 34 , 416–428.

Battu, H., Belfield, C., & Sloane, P. (1999). Overeducation among graduates: A cohort view. Education Economics , 7 , 21–38.

Bauer, T. (2002). Educational mismatch and wages: A panel analysis. Economics of Education Review, 21 , 221–229.

Becker, G. (1964). Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education . National Bureau of Economic Research.

Google Scholar  

Campos-Soria, J., García Pozo, A., & Sánchez Ollero, J. (2015). Gender wage inequality and labour mobility in the hospitality sector. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 49 , 73–82.

Capsada-Munsech, Q. (2019). Measuring overeducation: Incidence, correlation and overlaps across indicators and countries. Social Indicators Research, 145 , 279–301.

Caroleo, F., & Pastore, F. (2018). Overeducation at a glance. Determinants and wage effects of the educational mismatch based on AlmaLaurea Data. Social Indicators Research, 137 , 999–1032.

Carroll, D., & Tani, M. (2013). Over-education of recent higher education graduates: New Australian panel evidence. Economics of Education Review, 32 , 207–218.

Chevalier, A. (2000). Graduate Over-Education in the UK. Centre for the Economics of Education Discussion Paper, 07, November.

Dekker, R., de Grip, A., & Heijke, H. (2002). The effects of training and overeducation on career mobility in sequential labor market. International Journal of Manpower, 23 , 106–136.

Delaney, J., McGuinness, S., Pouliakas, K., & Redmond, P. (2020). Educational expansion and overeducation of young graduates: A comparative analysis of 30 European countries. Oxford Review of Education, 46 , 10–29.

Deželan, T., & Hafner, F. (2014). First-job educational and skill match. An empirical investigation of political science graduates in Slovenia. International Journal of Manpower, 35 , 553–575.

Di Pietro, G., & Urwin, P. (2006). Education and skills mismatch in the Italian graduate labour market. Applied Economics, 38 , 79–93.

Dolton, P. & Silles, M. (2008). The effects of over-education on earnings in the graduate labour market. Economics of Education Review, 27 , 125–139.

Dolton, P., & Vignoles, P. (2000). The incidence and the effects of overeducation in the UK graduate labour market. Economics of Education Review, 19 , 179–198.

Duncan, J., & Hoffman, S. (1981). The incidence and wage effects of overeducation. Economics of Education Review, 1 , 75–86.

Gaeta, L., Lavadera, G., & Pastore, F. (2021). The effect of job-education vertical mismatch on wages among recent PhD graduates: Evidence from an instrumental variable analysis. Italian Economic Journal . https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-021-00167-y

Garcia-Mainar, I., & Montuenga, V. (2019). The signalling role of over-education and qualifications mismatch. Journal of Policy Modeling, 41 , 99–119.

Groot, W., & Massen van den Brink, H. (2000). Overeducation in the labor market: A meta-analysis. International Journal of Manpower, 21 , 584–595.

Hartog, J. (2000). Over-education and earnings: Where are we, where should we go? Economics of Education Review, 19 , 131–147.

Kler, P. (2005). Graduate overeducation in Australia: A comparison of the mean and objective methods. Education Economics, 13 , 47–72.

Korpi, T., & Tahlin, M. (2009). Educational mismatch, wages, and wage growth: Overeducation in Sweden, 1974–2000. Labour Economics, 16 , 183–193.

Li, Q., & Racine, J. (2004). Cross-validated local linear nonparametric regression. Statistica Sinica, 14 , 485–512.

Liu, Y., Yin, L., & Guo, J. (2021). The quality of higher education and overeducation: Where should higher education funding go? Finance Research Letters, 41 , 101824

Mavromaras, K., McGuinness, S., O’Leary, N., Sloane, P., & Wei, Z. (2013). Job mismatches and labour market outcomes: Panel evidence on university graduates. Economic Record, 89 , 382–395.

McGuinness, S. (2006). Overeducation in labor market. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20 , 387–418.

Mincer, J., & Polachek, S. (1974). Family investments in human capital: Earnings of women. Journal of Political Economy, 82 , S76–S108.

Nieto, S., & Ramos, R. (2017). Overeducation, skills and wage penalty: Evidence for Spain using PIAAC data. Social Indicators Research, 134 , 219–236.

Nordin, M., Persson, I., & Rooth, D. (2010). Education-occupation mismatch: Is there an income penalty? Economics of Education Review, 29 , 1047–1059.

Ordine, P., & Rose, G. (2015). The effects of family background, university quality and educational mismatch on wage: An analysis using a young cohort of Italian graduates. Education Economics, 23 , 213–237.

Park, K. (2021). Doctoral education, job mismatch, and wage consequences in South Korea: A propensity score matching approach. Journal of Asian and African Studies . https://doi.org/10.1177/00219096211052978

Park, K., & Jang, D. (2019). The wage effects of over-education among young STEM graduates. The Singapore Economic Review, 64 , 1351–1370.

Preston, A. (1997). Where are we now with human capital theory in Australia? The Economic Record, 73 , 51–78.

Robst, J. (1995). College quality and overeducation. Economics of Education Review, 14 , 221–228.

Robst, J. (2007). Education, college major, and job match: Gender differences in reasons for mismatch. Economics of Education Review, 26 , 397–407.

Rubb, S. (2006). Educational mismatches and earnings: Extensions of occupational mobility theory and evidence of human capital depreciation. Education Economics, 14 , 135–154.

Sánchez, N., & McGuinness, S. (2011). Decomposing the impacts of overeducation and overskilling on earnings and job satisfaction: An analysis using REFLEX data. Education Economics, 23 , 419–432.

Sattinger, M. (1993). Assignment models of the distribution of earnings. Journal of Economic Literature, 31 , 831–880.

Sellami, S., Verhaest, D., Nonneman, W., & Van Trier, W. (2017). The impact of educational mismatches on wages: The influence of measurement error and unobserved heterogeneity. The B.e Journal of Economic Analysis, 17 , 1–21.

Sicherman, N. (1991). Overeducation in the labor market. Journal of Labor Economics, 9 , 101–122.

Sicherman, N., & Galor, O. (1990). A theory of career mobility. Journal of Political Economy, 98 , 169–192.

Sloane, P. (2003). Much ado about nothing? What does the overeducation literature really tell us? In F. Büchel, A. de Grip, & A. Mertens (Eds.), Overeducation in Europe. Current issues in theory and policy (pp. 11–48). Edward Elgar Publishing.

Thurow, L. C. (1975). Generating inequality: Mechanisms of distribution in the U.S. economy . New York: Basic Books.

Book   Google Scholar  

Turmo-Garuz, J., Bartual-Figueras, M., & Sierra-Martinez, F. (2019). Factors associated with overeducation among recent graduates during labour market integration: The case of catalonia (Spain). Social Indicators Research, 144 , 1273–1301.

Verdugo, R., & Verdugo, N. (1989). The impact of surplus schooling on earnings. Journal of Human Resources, 24 , 629–643.

Verhaest, D., & Omey, E. (2010). The determinants of overeducation: Different measures, different outcomes? International Journal of Manpower, 31 , 608–625.

Wu, N., & Wang, Q. (2018). Wage penalty of overeducation: New micro-evidence from China. China Economic Review, 50 , 206–217.

Zhu, R. (2014). The impact of major-job mismatch on college graduates’ early career earnings: Evidence from China. Education Economics, 22 , 511–528.

Download references

This research has benefited from the financial support of the Fondo para la Investigación Científica y Tecnológica (FONCyT) under grant PICT 2015-1771. All opinions, as any remaining errors, are the sole responsibility of the authors.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Facultad de Ciencias Económicas, Universidad Nacional de Córdoba, Córdoba, Argentina

Mariana Olga De Santis, María Cecilia Gáname & Pedro Esteban Moncarz

Centro de Investigaciones en Ciencias Económicas, CIECS (UNC-CONICET), Córdoba, Argentina

Consejo Nacional de Investigaciones Científicas y Técnicas, Ciudad Autónoma de Buenos Aires, Buenos Aires, Argentina

Pedro Esteban Moncarz

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pedro Esteban Moncarz .

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest.

There is no research-related conflict of interest.

Ethical Approval

The surveys conducted for this study did not require prior approval by an ethical body according to the rules of the funding institution or the Facultad de Ciencias Económicas of the Universidad Nacional de Córdoba.

Consent to Participate

Not applicable. Due to the nature of the research, the informed consent of the respondents was not required.

Consent for Publication

Additional information, publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

De Santis, M.O., Gáname, M.C. & Moncarz, P.E. The Impact of Overeducation on Wages of Recent Economic Sciences Graduates. Soc Indic Res 163 , 409–445 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-022-02905-w

Download citation

Accepted : 14 February 2022

Published : 05 March 2022

Issue Date : August 2022

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-022-02905-w

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Overeducation
  • Economic sciences graduates
  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research
  • Browse All Articles
  • Newsletter Sign-Up

economics case studies wages and education

  • 16 May 2023

How KKR Got More by Giving Ownership to the Factory Floor: ‘My Kids Are Going to College!’

KKR turned around a struggling door company and sold it for 10 times its investment—giving factory workers a life-changing cut of the returns. A case study by Ethan Rouen and Dennis Campbell offers lessons for companies trying to instill an owner's mindset in employees.

economics case studies wages and education

  • 07 Feb 2023
  • Research & Ideas

Supervisor of Sandwiches? More Companies Inflate Titles to Avoid Extra Pay

What does an assistant manager of bingo actually manage? Increasingly, companies are falsely classifying hourly workers as managers to avoid paying an estimated $4 billion a year in overtime, says research by Lauren Cohen.

economics case studies wages and education

  • 15 Oct 2020

IT Job Wages Are No Longer 'Exceptional'

Wage growth in IT jobs has moderated following the dot-com boom, according to new research by Ruiqing Sam Cao and Shane Greenstein. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

economics case studies wages and education

  • 14 Sep 2020
  • Working Paper Summaries

Digital Labor Market Inequality and the Decline of IT Exceptionalism

The experience in five cities accounts for almost all the wage inequality in IT wages in the US between 2000 and 2018. Overall that brought IT wages closer to STEM wages.

economics case studies wages and education

  • 25 Mar 2019

The Secret Life of Supply Chains

While US policymakers and politicians focus on reviving the manufacturing sector, Mercedes Delgado and Karen Mills unearth a source of better jobs hidden in plain sight. Call it the supply chain economy. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 29 Apr 2018

Analyzing the Aftermath of a Compensation Reduction

This study of the effects of compensation cuts in a large sales organization provides a unique lens for analyzing the link between compensation schemes, worker performance, and turnover.

  • 05 May 2017

Survival of the Fittest: The Impact of the Minimum Wage on Firm Exit

This study examines the impact of minimum wage increases on restaurant closures in the San Francisco Bay Area, using data from 2008 through 2016 from the review platform Yelp. The study demonstrates that higher minimum wages increase closure rates among lower-rated restaurants, while higher-rated restaurants are largely insulated from changes.

  • 21 Dec 2015

Wage Elasticities in Working and Volunteering: The Role of Reference Points in a Laboratory Study

Nonprofit organizations often rely on reference points—explicit or implicit targets and goals—to encourage more effort from volunteers. This study finds that effort does tend to cluster around reference levels, so this may be perceived as a very effective strategy. Yet reference levels can potentially backfire: in response to higher volunteer wages or productivity, volunteers may reduce their effort so as to meet the reference level.

  • 30 Nov 2015

Donors Are Turned Off by Overhead Costs. Here’s What Charities Can Do

Elizabeth A. Keenan and colleagues find that charitable donors are willing to stomach the idea of overhead costs—as long as they know someone else’s donation is covering them. A field study helped one organization nearly triple its solicited donations. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 09 Nov 2015

These Employers Pay Higher Salaries than Necessary

Some employers using online freelance marketplaces for the first time pay more than they have to for workers. Why? An information imbalance that job seekers can exploit, as explained in research by professor Christopher T. Stanton. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 10 Aug 2015

Why a Federal Rule on CEO Pay Disclosure May Get You In Trouble With Customers

The SEC is expected to adopt a rule requiring every public firm to disclose the ratio of the CEO's salary to the median salary of the firm's employees. And it turns out that customers prefer shopping from retailers with low pay ratios, according to new research by Bhavya Mohan, Michael Norton, and Rohit Deshpandé. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 06 Jul 2015

Money and Quotas Motivate the Sales Force Best

Bonus programs are effective for motivating sales people, but also costly for companies to maintain. Doug Chung and Das Narayandas study several compensation schemes to see which work best. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 16 Jun 2015

Paying Up for Fair Pay: Consumers Prefer Firms with Lower CEO-to-Worker Pay Ratios

The pay ratio of CEOs to average workers has long been a question of interest to both employees and investors. It also matters to consumers, as shown by new research conducted by the authors of this paper. A firm with a high (1000 to 1) ratio needs to offer a 50 percent discount in order to garner as favorable consumer impressions as a firm with a low (5 to 1) pay ratio. Even if pay ratio disclosure does not become legally mandated, these results suggest that firms with low pay ratios relative to competitors may wish to begin to disclose this information voluntarily. Closed for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 04 Feb 2014

From Crowds to Collaborators: Initiating Effort and Catalyzing Interactions Among Online Creative Workers

Online "organizations" are becoming a major engine for knowledge development in a variety of domains such as Wikipedia and open source software development. Many online platforms involve collaboration and coordination among members to reach common goals. In this sense, they are collaborative communities. This paper asks: What factors most inspire online teams to begin to collaborate and to do so creatively and effectively? The authors analyze a data set of 260 individuals randomly assigned to 52 teams tasked with developing working solutions to a complex innovation problem over 10 days, with varying cash incentives. Findings showed that although cash incentives stimulated a significant boost of effort per se, cash incentives did not transform the nature of the work process or affect the level of collaboration. In addition, at a basic yet striking level, the likelihood that an individual chooses to participate depended on whether teammates were themselves active. Moreover, communications among teammates led to more communications, and communications among teammates also stimulated greater continuous levels of effort. Overall, the study sheds light on how perspectives on incentives, predominant in economics, and perspectives on social processes and interactions, predominant in research on organizational behavior and teams, can be better understood. Key concepts include: An individual's likelihood of being active in online collaboration increases by about 41 percent with each additional active teammate. Management could provide communications channels to make the efforts of other members more visible. This is important in the design of systems for online work as it helps members to confirm that others are actively contributing. Closed for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 29 Oct 2013

Do Employees Work Harder for Higher Pay?

In a recent field study, Duncan Gilchrist, Michael Luca, and Deepak Malhotra set out to answer a basic question: "Do employees work harder when they are paid more?" Closed for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 24 Oct 2013

When $3+$1 > $4: The Effect of Gift Salience on Employee Effort in an Online Labor Market

Do employees work harder when they are paid more? This study shows that paying above-market wages, per se, does not have an effect on effort. The authors offered an experiment in a field setting that allowed them to test for the conditions under which higher wages elicit higher effort. They hired three groups of workers for a data entry task on the online labor market oDesk.com, telling them all that this was a one-time job. Group one ("3") was hired at $3 per hour. Group two ("3+1") was also hired at $3 per hour, but before starting work, people in group two were told that there was unexpectedly extra money in the budget and they would instead be paid $4 per hour. Group three ("4") was hired directly at $4 per hour, so that the "extra" money would not signal a salient "gift" from the employer. Our findings show that higher wages in which the gift was salient (3+1) led to higher and more persistent effort. However, higher wages by themselves (4) had no effect on effort compared to the lower wage (3) condition. Moreover, higher effort in the 3+1 group was strongest for employees with the most experience on oDesk, and those who had worked most recently on oDesk-exactly the kind of workers for whom our $1 additional payment was likely to be most salient (e.g., because it is not common in this labor market). Key concepts include: An employer has the ability to set an employee's reference point, and giving a surprise gift can be more impactful than simply paying higher wages. Targeted gifts-aimed at those who are most likely to interpret the additional reward as a gift-can be a cost-effective mechanism to reward employees, improve morale and increase productivity. However, reciprocity and gift giving are unlikely to explain all types of "efficiency wages" (i.e., "above market" wages) as we see them in the world around us because high wages that are baked into the hiring wage contract do not elicit the same productivity increase, but may induce greater effort by increasing the desire to keep a high-paying job if continued employment is possible. Closed for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 04 Jun 2013

Prosocial Bonuses Increase Employee Satisfaction and Team Performance

Designing effective incentive schemes is a central challenge for a wide range of organizations, from multinational corporations to academic departments. In pursuit of identifying the most effective strategies, organizations have devised an impressive variety of such bonuses, from fixed salaries to pay-per-performance, from commissions to end-of-year bonuses. In this paper, the authors suggest that the wide variety in such schemes masks a shared assumption: That the best way to motivate employees is to reward them with money that they then spend on themselves. The authors—Lalin Anik, Lara B. Aknin, Michael I. Norton, Elizabeth W. Dunn, and Jordi Quoidbach—propose an alternative means of incentivizing employees—what they term "prosocial bonuses"—in which organizations provide employees with bonuses used to engage in positive actions towards charities and coworkers, from donating money to remote countries to taking a coworker to lunch. The authors examine the impact of these prosocial bonuses on employee satisfaction and team performance, by reporting results from field experiments in settings ranging from bank employees in Australia to pharmaceutical sales representatives in Belgium to dodgeball teams in Canada. Overall, results suggest that a minor adjustment to employee bonuses—shifting the focus from the self to others—can produce measurable benefits for employees and organizations. Key concepts include: When organizations give employees the opportunity to spend money on others—whether their coworkers or those in need—both the employees and the company can benefit, with increased happiness and job satisfaction and even improved team performance. Prosocial bonuses can benefit both individuals and teams, on both psychological and "bottom line" indicators, in both the short and long-term. Prosocial bonuses could backfire if companies introduce them as a replacement for more standard bonuses, rather than as an additional incentive. Closed for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 08 Apr 2013

How to Demotivate Your Best Employees

Many companies hand out awards such as "employee of the month," but do they work to motivate performance? Not really, says professor Ian Larkin. In fact, they may turn off your best employees altogether. Closed for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 12 Feb 2013

Do Bonuses Enhance Sales Productivity? A Dynamic Structural Analysis of Bonus-Based Compensation Plans

Personal selling is a primary marketing mix tool for most B2B firms to generate sales. Yet there is little research on how the compensation plan motivates a sales force and affects performance. This paper develops and estimates a dynamic structural model of sales force response to a compensation plan with various components: salary, commissions, lump-sum bonus for achieving quotas, and different commission rates beyond achieving quotas. Overall, the analysis helps assess the impact of (1) different components of compensation and (2) the differential importance of periodic bonuses on performance on different segments of sales people. Key concepts include: A quota-bonus scheme used by a firm increases performance of the sales force by serving as intermediary goals and pushing employees to meet targets. Features such as overachievement compensation reduce the problems associated with sales agents slacking off when they get close to achieving their quota. Quarterly bonuses serve as a continuous evaluation scheme to keep sales agents within striking distance of their annual quotas. In the absence of quarterly bonuses, failure in the early periods to accomplish targets causes agents to fall behind more often than in the presence of quarterly bonuses. Thus, a quarterly bonus serves as a valuable sub-goal that helps the sales force stay on track in achieving their overall goal. Quarterly bonuses are especially valuable to low performers. Overachievement commissions increase performance among the highest performers. Closed for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 27 Nov 2012

No Margin, No Mission? A Field Experiment on Incentives for Pro-Social Tasks

Organizations from large corporations to NGOs use a range of nonfinancial performance rewards to motivate their employees, and these rewards are highly valued. While theory has suggested mechanisms through which nonfinancial incentives can elicit employee effort, evidence on the mechanisms, and on their effectiveness relative to financial incentives, remains scarce. This paper helps to fill this gap by providing evidence from a collaboration with a public health organization based in Lusaka, Zambia, that recruits and trains hairdressers and barbers to sell condoms in their shops. This setting is representative of many health delivery programs in developing countries where embedded community agents are called upon to deliver services and products, but finding an effective way to motivate them remains a significant challenge. Findings show the effectiveness of financial and nonfinancial rewards for increasing sales of condoms. Agents who are offered nonfinancial rewards ("stars" in this setting) exert more effort than either those offered financial margins or those offered volunteer contracts. Key concepts include: Nonfinancial rewards can motivate agents in settings where there are limits to the use of financial incentives. Nonfinancial rewards elicit effort by leveraging the agents' pro-social motivation and by facilitating social comparisons among agents. Closed for comment; 0 Comments.

IMAGES

  1. APAC Economics 3.2.1 Wages and Education-2.pdf

    economics case studies wages and education

  2. Solving Case Study in Economics: A Complete Guide

    economics case studies wages and education

  3. A Level Economics Case Studies: Theme 1 (FREE)

    economics case studies wages and education

  4. Copy of 1.1 Scarcity and Economics- Case Study 1.pdf

    economics case studies wages and education

  5. The truth about the relationship between education and earnings

    economics case studies wages and education

  6. Complete Guide to GCE A-Level Economics Case Studies

    economics case studies wages and education

VIDEO

  1. March 2024 AS Economics Paper 2 case study solved 9708

  2. Important Questions of micro economics| Case studies of Micro

  3. Business Economics|| Types of Wages and theories of wage|| B.com 1st year ||Commerce Room

  4. Economics Simplified ! For Students and Professionals -Business Case Study Analysis

  5. Texes EC-6 Core Subjects Social Studies: Economics, Part 3

  6. Teacher Salaries: Exploring the Financial Struggles of Educators

COMMENTS

  1. Impact of Educational Attainment on Wages Anri Sorel and Erin Shinners

    The effect of educational attainment on wages and subsequent economic growth is a widely tested model in U.S. labor economics. The importance of studying education cannot be understated, as it has a strong correlation to different facets of development and financial well-being on the individual, state, and global levels.

  2. The Economic Benefits of Educational Attainment

    Douglas Holtz-Eakin, Tom Lee. The Economic Benefits of Educational Attainment. Executive Summary. Education is vital for a highly skilled and productive labor force. This study seeks to quantify the relationships between additional educational attainment and employment opportunities, wage rates, and aggregate economic growth.

  3. The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings

    1. Introduction and overview. Education plays a central role in modern labor markets. Hundreds of studies in many different countries and time periods have confirmed that better-educated individuals earn higher wages, experience less unemployment, and work in more prestigious occupations than their less-educated counterparts. 1 Despite the overwhelming evidence of a positive correlation ...

  4. PDF Education's Impact on Economic Growth and Productivity

    increase in wages (Psacharopoulos and Patrinos 2004). Education has also been identified as a driver of improved demographic and health outcomes, contributing to decreases in infant mortality and ...

  5. PDF Education and Economic Growth

    Conclusions. Economic growth determines the future economic well-being of a country, making understanding the determinants of growth a high-priority area of economic research. The analysis of how education affects growth makes a strong case that the skills of the population are by far the most important factor.

  6. The Economics of Education: A Case Study of Wachuset Regional High School

    Chapter One is about the economic and social effects of education, Chapter Two discusses economies of scale in high schools, and Chapter Three explains. the education production function. The last chapter, Chapter Four, is a case study of one school district in central Massachusetts, the Wachusett Regional School District. By.

  7. The economic case for education: Education Economics: Vol 24 , No 1

    The case for education can be made from many perspectives. This paper makes the case for education based on economic outcomes. Surveying the most recent empirical evidence, it shows the crucial role of education for individual and societal prosperity. Education is a leading determinant of economic growth, employment, and earnings in modern ...

  8. Does education raise productivity and wages equally? The moderating

    We estimate the impact of education on productivity, wage costs and productivity-wage gaps (i.e. profits) using Belgian linked panel data. Findings highlight that educational credentials have a stronger impact on productivity than on wage costs. Firms' profitability is found to rise when lower educated workers are substituted by higher educated ones. This effect is found to be more ...

  9. The Effect of Education and Experience on Wages: The Case Study of

    This paper examines the effect of education and experience on wages of workers in Thailand, especially the differences in urban and rural labor markets. This paper proposes that both education and experience significantly impacts wages. The study estimates are based on the Mincerian wage equation with a large cross-section data of Thai individuals. The results suggest that education and ...

  10. PDF Does Education Raise Productivity and Wages Equally? The Moderating

    A vast literature examines the impact of education on wages (Ashenfelter et al., 1999; Card, ... asymmetries, social norms or labour market regulations) suggest that this is probably the case. The aim of this paper is threefold. ... some studies suggest that education fosters output per worker and income per capita (Krueger and Lindahl, 2001 ...

  11. PDF Education and economic growth

    Education and economic growth Anna Valero ISSN 2042-2695. ... including externalities, is then summarised. Beyond studies that link human capital to economic performance directly, there are numerous studies that have explore the relationships between human ... which case α and (1 - α) are also the shares of profits and wages in income ...

  12. PDF E (EENEE)

    This report makes the. economic case for education. Based on the most recent empirical evidence, it shows the crucial role of education for individual and societal prosperity. Education is a leading determinant of economic growth, employment, and earnings in modern knowledge-based economies such as the European Union.

  13. Skill Formation, Public Expenditure on Education and Wage Inequality

    In this case, the wage inequality improves due to the subsidy if \(\theta _{L1 ... The impact of the public spending on education on the wage inequality is largely plausible with our analytical model. ... Working paper no. 260, Society for the Study of Economic Inequality. Crouch, C., D. Finegold, and M. Sako. 1999. Are skills the answer: the ...

  14. The impact of education expansion on wage inequality: Applied Economics

    The structure effect of education expansion on income inequality is negative, when average education increases one year, the income gap between 80th and 20th will decrease 1.2%, in other words, education expansion decreases income inequality by allowing a wide range of individuals to attend college. However, this effect is offset by the price ...

  15. Immigration, Wages, and Education: A Labour Market Equilibrium ...

    Immigration, Wages, and Education: A Labour Market Equilibrium Structural Model JOAN LLULL Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, MOVE, and Barcelona GSE ... [18:16 20/6/2018 rdx053.tex] RESTUD: The Review of Economic Studies Page: 1853 1852-1896 LLULL IMMIGRATION, WAGES, AND EDUCATION 1853

  16. Compensating Wage Differentials in Labor Markets: Empirical Challenges

    In 2020, the worker with the median wage in the United States earned $19.15 per hour in earnings and their employers paid an additional $9.25 per hour, or 48 percent of wages, in total benefits (US Bureau of Labor Statistics 2020).

  17. (PDF) The Wage Equation: Modelling the effect of Education on Wage

    The Signaling Theory forms the basis of this paper. This paper seeks to study the importance of. Education as wages determinant, to estimate, interpret and evaluate an econometric model of the ...

  18. The Impact of Overeducation on Wages of Recent Economic Sciences

    The vertical mismatch is approximated by the relationship between the person's level of formal education, undergraduate studies in the case of our sample, and the level of education required by the job. ... M.O., Gáname, M.C. & Moncarz, P.E. The Impact of Overeducation on Wages of Recent Economic Sciences Graduates. Soc Indic Res 163, 409 ...

  19. Government Spending on Education and Economic Growth: A Case Study of

    Government Spending on Education and Economic Growth: A Case Study of West African Countries. By Lloyd Ahamefule AMAGHIONYEODIWE Department of Business and Economics, ... individuals acquire knowledge which can be transformed into higher wages and higher economic growth. Investment in educated and skilled workers will bring out efficient use of ...

  20. PDF Labor Economics and Public Policy

    The course emphasizes the link between research and public policy. Topics include labor supply and labor demand, taxes and transfers, minimum wages, immigration, human capital, education production, inequality, discrimination, and labor unions. The first half of the course meets with graduate labor economics, 14.661.

  21. Wages: Articles, Research, & Case Studies on Wages- HBS Working Knowledge

    This study examines the impact of minimum wage increases on restaurant closures in the San Francisco Bay Area, using data from 2008 through 2016 from the review platform Yelp. The study demonstrates that higher minimum wages increase closure rates among lower-rated restaurants, while higher-rated restaurants are largely insulated from changes.

  22. Trade unions, stigma and legitimacy: A case study about academic wages

    The case study investigates trade union discourse by collecting and analysing campaign materials about academic wages across British universities over 18 years. The results suggest trade unions tried to stigmatize British universities for not engaging in consultation and negotiation; acting with honesty and good faith; or being transparent and ...

  23. APAC Economics 3.2.1 Wages and Education-2.pdf

    Economics Case Studies Wages and Education Case Study #1-Read the scenario and answer the questions given the information below. You‟re 23 years old and you‟re graduating from college this fall. You‟re a little worried about finding a job sin ce most students graduate in the spring and look for jobs in the summer.

  24. Hiring and Wages are Up, Reinforcing the Economy's Resilience

    Strong jobs growth and the rise in the unemployment rate to 4%—its first time at that level in over two years—offered a mixed view of a labor market. Photo: Jamie Kelter Davis/Bloomberg News U ...